sábado, 4 de novembro de 2006

634) Sobre o papel do Estado no (NAO) desenvolvimento economico...

Depois do debate sobre as virtudes respectivas dos modelos nórdico e anglo-saxão no processo de crescimento, desenvolvimento econômico, social e tecnológico e na distribuição mais equitativa de renda (ver o post nr. 631, mais abaixo), volto ao problema, pela transcrição de um artigo publicado num jornal belga.
Recomendo, para o pleno aproveitamento da leitura e o entendimento perfeito dos argumentos, em vistas dos muitos gráficos explicativos existentes no texto, uma consulta ao link seguinte: http://www.brusselsjournal.com/node/510

Eu recomendaria também, fortemente, uma consulta a este trabalho do mesmo grupo de economistas: Causes for Growth Differentials in Europe.

The Myth of the Scandinavian Model
By Martin De Vlieghere
The Brussels Journal, 25 november 2005

This article was written by Martin De Vlieghere, Paul Vreymans and Willy De Wit of the Flemish think tank Work for All.

“America’s social model is flawed, but so is France’s,” the Parisian newspaper Le Monde recently wrote. According to Le Monde Europe should adopt the “Scandinavian model,” which is said to combine the economic efficiency of the Anglo-Saxon social model with the welfare state benefits of the continental European ones. On the eve of the EU’s Hampton Court Summit (October 27), one could even read that “Britain might be forced to discuss the advantages of Scandinavian models, which rely on more social security.”

The praise for the Nordic model comes from Bruegel, a new Brussels-based think tank, “whose aim is to contribute to the quality of economic policymaking in Europe.” The think tank is a Franco-German government initiative and is heavily funded by EU governments and corporations. In October Bruegel published a study “Globalisation and the Reform of European Social Models” [pdf] propagating the Nordic model.

A paper [pdf] from the economics department of Ghent University does the same. This paper, Fiscal Policy Employment and Growth: Why is the Euro Area Lagging Behind, was also subsidized by the government. In the selection of data comparing the performance of EU economies, the authors arbitrarily eliminated Ireland, Spain and Portugal (three of the four best performing EU economies) from their research and added oil-producing non-EU member Norway (which has a GDP more than 20% of which is based on income from oil). It is hardly imaginable that professors of one of Belgium’s major universities would not be aware of how this arbitrary selection must distort the results. Hence one must read their text as an ideological pamphlet rather than a scientific study.

However, despite Bruegel, distorted academic studies and the European media’s praise, the efficiency of the major Scandinavian economies is a myth. The Swedish and Finnish welfare states have been going through a long period of decline. In the early 1990s they were virtually bankrupt. Between 1990 and 1995 unemployment increased five-fold. The Scandinavian countries have not been able to recover.

The implosion of the welfare state
In 1970, Sweden’s level of prosperity was one quarter above Belgium’s. By 2003 Sweden had fallen to 14th place from 5th in the prosperity index, two places behind Belgium. According to OECD figures, Denmark was the 3rd most prosperous economy in the world in 1970, immediately behind Switzerland and the United States. In 2003, Denmark was 7th. Finland did badly as well. From 1989 to 2003, while Ireland rose from 21st to 4th place, Finland fell from 9th to 15th place.

Ranking.gif

Prosperity.gif

Together with Italy, these three Scandinavian countries are the worst performing economies in the entire European Union. Rather than taking them as an example, Europe’s politicians should shun the Scandinavian recipes.

Jobs
While a poorly performing economy such as Belgium’s was able to create 8% new jobs between 1981 and 2003, Sweden and Finland were unable to create any jobs at all in over two decades. Denmark did a little better because it “activated” its labour market by making it more “flexible.” It became easier for employers to fire people. For workers in the construction industry the term of notice was reduced to five days. Unemployment benefits were restricted in time, while those who had been unemployed for a long time, and young people could lose benefits if they refuse to accept jobs, including low-productivity jobs below their level of training or education. The result is that productivity growth in Denmark is lower than in Sweden and Finland.

Jobcreation.gif

These draconian measures reduced the unemployment rate, but did not eliminate the cause of unemployment, namely the total lack of motivation on the part of employees and employers resulting from the extremely high taxation level. Despite the painful measures, the growth of Danish productivity and prosperity has been substandard. Disappointment in Danish politicians is one of the reasons for the rise of the far right.

Weak government, bad government
Why are the Scandinavian countries doing such a bad job, despite their Protestant work ethic and devotion to duty? The main cause is the essence of the nanny state: its very high tax level. Between 1990 and 2005 the average overall tax burden was 55% in Finland, 58% in Denmark and 61% in Sweden. This is almost one and a half times the OECD average.

GwartneysLaw.gif

In his research into the causes of growth differences between OECD economies the American economist James Gwartney showed that there was a direct correlation between economic growth and tax burden. The higher the level of taxation, the lower the growth rate. The explanation for this phenomenon is as logical as it is simple. The higher the tax level, the lower the incentive for people to make a productive contribution to society. The higher the fiscal burden, the more resources flow from the productive sector to the ever more inefficient government apparatus.

Ireland: the efficient alternative
Ireland has proved that a substantial lowering of the taxation level can become the motor for launching even the most slackish economy into full gear. A drastic reduction of the Irish tax rate, from 53% in 1986 to its current 35% , has led to a continuous boom of wealth creation at an average rate of 5.6% during the past two decades, while the number of jobs has grown by over 50%. In barely 18 years Ireland jumped from the 22nd to the 4th place in the OECD prosperity ranking. Ireland did not reduce its social welfare benefits. On the contrary. The unprecedented growth led to an increase of fiscal revenue and social expenditure. It was sufficient to improve the productivity of the government.

TaxBurden.gif

One crucial element of the Irish model is its “fair tax” system, in which there is less emphasis on taxing labour and profit and slightly more on taxing consumption. This balance between direct and indirect taxation motivates labourers and entrepreneurs to make productive contributions. It stimulates new initiatives and guarantees a high degree of participation.

Such a fiscal system does not put the entire burden of financing social security on domestic production. Indeed, a consumption tax ensures that foreign production also contributes evenly.

Productivity.gif

The Irish model combines the so-called “active welfare state” of continental Europe with the Anglo-Saxon liberal economy in a balanced fashion. The model is efficient. Ireland surpasses all other EU members in prosperity, job creation, social expenditure and productivity per working hour.

Investing in the future
The difference between the wealth destructive Scandinavian model and the booming Irish alternative is obvious for all to see. Strangely enough, however, the French and German governments do not seem to notice. Those in Belgium do not, either. The Belgian government recently proposed a new policy plan inspired by the Danish model. The tax level is not reduced, the fiscal burden is not being shifted from production to consumption, but instead from one production factor (labour) to another (capital) which is already overburdened.

SavingsRate.gif

Saving is discouraged, too. After deducting inflation and the witholding tax, which under the European savings taxation directive will soon amount to 35%, the real net interest rate will be –2%. This means that every person in his thirties who is saving 1.00 euro today, will only have the equivalent of 0.54 euro when he turns 60. In barely six years the Belgian savings rate has already dropped by more than a quarter: from 12.4% in 1998 to 9.1% in 2004. The savings rate will drop even further, thereby drying up all reserves for investment. Like work, saving and investing, too, must be profitable if people are to engage in these activities.

Excessive taxation
2004 witnessed a record world economic growth of 5%. China and India are booming, the US and Japan are recovering. Gwartney’s findings explain why continental West European countries, such as Belgium, did not see their economies grow. The Belgian tax burden is 9% higher than the OECD average and 15% higher than the tax level in the US and Japan. If continental Western Europe does not change its policies, its relative impoverishment today will soon turn into absolute pauperization.

PublicSpending.gif

Its tax structure is not adapted to the challenges of globalization. Taxes on production are the opposite of import taxes. They double Europe’s production costs and, in doing so, halve its productivity. Like protectionism they lead to distortions in world trade, but they do so in the opposite direction. Ever more rapidly, continental Western Europe is losing its semi labour-intensive sectors to countries where productivity is even lower than in Western Europe. This move from high productivity to low productivity countries is a waste. It is not only a catastrophe for Western Europe’s employment. It is also bad for the world at large because the highly productive production apparatus and infrastructure of Western Europe is not used to its full capacity. This leads to less than optimal global labour division and wealth creation.

Politicians must realize that economic growth is not brought about by fiscally punishing productive citizens, nor by collective impoverishment and social welfare cuts, but by cutting taxes and bureaucracy. Ireland has shown that it can be done and how to do it.
Source URL: http://www.brusselsjournal.com/node/510

4 comentários:

  1. Excelente discussão, principalmente quando visualizamos a queda - e os resquícios - do welfare state. A Suécia já disse que vai até o fim (ou até que não há fim).

    A pergunta que paira é "será que a fórmula do sucesso de uma nação reside na organização de seu Estado?"

    De início, cabe lembrar que desenvolvimento não está necessariamente ligado à economia.

    Post muito interessante, vale imprimir e ler novamente.

    Até! =)

    ResponderExcluir
  2. Em tempo, acabo de ver a sua resposta do meu último comentário.
    De fato, adoraria que tivesse sido possível comparecer ao lançamento do livro: título interessante - e instigante - e o que aqui está escrito já permite perceber a qualidade do mesmo.

    De qualquer forma, agradeço o convite.

    Segue meu email: carinasenna@gmail.com

    ResponderExcluir
  3. Sweden and Finland were unable to create any jobs at all in over two decades. Qual a taxa de desemprego desses países nas 2 décadas?
    Denmark did a little better because it “activated” its labour market by making it more “flexible.” It became easier for employers to fire people. É bem claro aqui a diferença que o autor não percebe, ele estabalece a importância da economia frente a da sociedade. Flexibilização traz mais trabalhos precários, informais, sem segurança, é bom analisar o conceito de trabalho decente da ONU.
    One crucial element of the Irish model is its “fair tax” system, in which there is less emphasis on taxing labour and profit and slightly more on taxing consumption. Famoso imposto regressivo, que temos em nosso país como exemplo, concentração de renda, muita pobreza, exclusão social. Como isso pode ser chamado de justo?
    Este texto tem um viés muito liberal, não é uma análise muito bem feita e se pode constatar que joga os dados não para o desenvolvimento de um debate mas para construir pensamentos prontos. O ponto principal dos países escandinavos é o bem estar social, a segurança social, IDH, etc, em nenhum momento vi dados sobre isso. Bem não se pode esperar muito de uma análise jornalística Européia.
    É necessário pensar no debate, muito baseado em Celso Furtado, a Economia deve se subordinar a Sociedade ou a Sociedade de se subordinar a Economia? Meu ponto de vista é que a economia deve trabalhar para a Sociedade, para o bem estar de seu povo, com emprego de qualidade, menor diferença social, combate a pobreza, e muito mais.
    Fica ai o comentário que pode facilmente entrar em um debate, aceito críticas.
    William Borgonovi- Estudante do ultimo ano de Economia Unicamp

    ResponderExcluir
  4. William Borgonovi,
    Estando na Unicamp, você só poderia mesmo apreciar Celso Furtado, os cepalinos e todos os keynesianos aloprados que pululam por ai.
    Apenas um conselho: tente diversificar suas leituras lendo trabalhos de economia realmente uteis.
    Veja, por exemplo, o site do NBER, dos EUA.
    DIversifique rapaz...
    Paulo Roberto de Almeida

    ResponderExcluir

Comentários são sempre bem-vindos, desde que se refiram ao objeto mesmo da postagem, de preferência identificados. Propagandas ou mensagens agressivas serão sumariamente eliminadas. Outras questões podem ser encaminhadas através de meu site (www.pralmeida.org). Formule seus comentários em linguagem concisa, objetiva, em um Português aceitável para os padrões da língua coloquial.
A confirmação manual dos comentários é necessária, tendo em vista o grande número de junks e spams recebidos.