A very, very long post... (without the graphics...; look at the printed edition).
Paulo Roberto de Almeida
Special report: State capitalism
The Economist,
Jan 21st 2012 | from the print edition
The visible hand
The crisis of Western liberal capitalism has coincided with the rise of
a powerful new form of state capitalism in emerging markets, says Adrian
Wooldridge
BEATRICE WEBB grew up as a fervent believer in
free markets and limited government. Her father was a self-made railway tycoon
and her mother an ardent free-trader. One of her family’s closest friends was
Herbert Spencer, the leading philosopher of Victorian liberalism. Spencer took
a shine to young Beatrice and treated her to lectures on the magic of the
market, the survival of the fittest and the evils of the state. But as Beatrice
grew up she began to have doubts. Why should the state not intervene in the
market to order children out of chimneys and into schools, or to provide
sustenance for the hungry and unemployed or to rescue failing industries? In
due course Beatrice became one of the leading architects of the welfare
state—and a leading apologist for Soviet communism.
The argument about the relative merits of the
state and the market that preoccupied young Beatrice has been raging ever
since. Between 1900 and 1970 the pro-statists had the wind in their sails. Governments
started off by weaving social safety nets and ended up by nationalising huge
chunks of the economy. Yet between 1970 and 2000 the free-marketeers made a
comeback. Ronald Reagan and Margaret Thatcher started a fashion across the West
for privatising state-run industries and pruning the welfare state. The Soviet
Union and its outriggers collapsed in ruins.
The era of free-market triumphalism has come to
a juddering halt, and the crisis that destroyed Lehman Brothers in 2008 is now
engulfing much of the rich world. The weakest countries, such as Greece, have
already been plunged into chaos. Even the mighty United States has seen the
income of the average worker contract every year for the past three years. The
Fraser Institute, a Canadian think-tank, which has been measuring the progress
of economic freedom for the past four decades, saw its worldwide “freedom
index” rise relentlessly from 5.5 (out of 10) in 1980 to 6.7 in 2007. But then
it started to move backwards.
The crisis of liberal capitalism has been
rendered more serious by the rise of a potent alternative: state capitalism,
which tries to meld the powers of the state with the powers of capitalism. It
depends on government to pick winners and promote economic growth. But it also
uses capitalist tools such as listing state-owned companies on the stockmarket
and embracing globalisation. Elements of state capitalism have been seen in the
past, for example in the rise of Japan in the 1950s and even of Germany in the
1870s, but never before has it operated on such a scale and with such
sophisticated tools.
State capitalism can claim the world’s most
successful big economy for its camp. Over the past 30 years China’s GDP has
grown at an average rate of 9.5% a year and its international trade by 18% in
volume terms. Over the past ten years its GDP has more than trebled to $11
trillion. China has taken over from Japan as the world’s second-biggest
economy, and from America as the world’s biggest market for many consumer
goods. The Chinese state is the biggest shareholder in the country’s 150
biggest companies and guides and goads thousands more. It shapes the overall
market by managing its currency, directing money to favoured industries and
working closely with Chinese companies abroad.
State capitalism can also claim some of the
world’s most powerful companies. The 13 biggest oil firms, which between them
have a grip on more than three-quarters of the world’s oil reserves, are all
state-backed. So is the world’s biggest natural-gas company, Russia’s Gazprom.
But successful state firms can be found in almost any industry. China Mobile is
a mobile-phone goliath with 600m customers. Saudi Basic Industries Corporation
is one of the world’s most profitable chemical companies. Russia’s Sberbank is
Europe’s third-largest bank by market capitalisation. Dubai Ports is the
world’s third-largest ports operator. The airline Emirates is growing at 20% a
year.
State capitalism is on the march, overflowing
with cash and emboldened by the crisis in the West. State companies make up 80%
of the value of the stockmarket in China, 62% in Russia and 38% in Brazil (see
chart). They accounted for one-third of the emerging world’s foreign direct
investment between 2003 and 2010 and an even higher proportion of its most
spectacular acquisitions, as well as a growing proportion of the very largest
firms: three Chinese state-owned companies rank among the world’s ten biggest
companies by revenue, against only two European ones (see chart). Add the
exploits of sovereign-wealth funds to the ledger, and it begins to look as if
liberal capitalism is in wholesale retreat: New York’s Chrysler Building (or
90% of it anyway) has fallen to Abu Dhabi and Manchester City football club to
Qatar. The Chinese have a phrase for it: “The state advances while the private
sector retreats.” This is now happening on a global scale.
This special report will focus on the new state
capitalism of the emerging world rather than the old state capitalism in
Europe, because it reflects the future rather than the past. The report will
look mainly at China, Russia and Brazil. The recent protests in Russia against
the rigging of parliamentary elections by Vladimir Putin, the prime minister,
have raised questions about the country’s political stability and, by implication,
the future of state capitalism there, but for the moment nothing much seems to
have changed. India will not be considered in detail because, although it has
some of the world’s biggest state-owned companies, they are more likely to be
leftovers of the Licence Raj rather than thrusting new national champions.
Today’s state capitalism also represents a
significant advance on its predecessors in several respects. First, it is
developing on a much wider scale: China alone accounts for a fifth of the
world’s population. Second, it is coming together much more quickly: China and
Russia have developed their formula for state capitalism only in the past
decade. And third, it has far more sophisticated tools at its disposal. The
modern state is more powerful than anything that has gone before: for example,
the Chinese Communist Party holds files on vast numbers of its citizens. It is
also far better at using capitalist tools to achieve its desired ends. Instead
of handing industries to bureaucrats or cronies, it turns them into companies
run by professional managers.
The
return of history
This special report will cast a sceptical eye
on state capitalism. It will raise doubts about the system’s ability to
capitalise on its successes when it wants to innovate rather than just catch
up, and to correct itself if it takes a wrong turn. Managing the system’s
contradictions when the economy is growing rapidly is one thing; doing so when
it hits a rough patch quite another. And state capitalism is plagued by cronyism
and corruption.
But the report will also argue that state
capitalism is the most formidable foe that liberal capitalism has faced so far.
State capitalists are wrong to claim that they combine the best of both worlds,
but they have learned how to avoid some of the pitfalls of earlier
state-sponsored growth. And they are flourishing in the dynamic markets of the
emerging world, which have been growing at an average of 5.5% a year against
the rich world’s 1.6% over the past few years and are likely to account for
half the world’s GDP by 2020.
State capitalism increasingly looks like the
coming trend. The Brazilian government has forced the departure of the boss of
Vale, a mining giant, for being too independent-minded. The French government
has set up a sovereign-wealth fund. The South African government is talking
openly about nationalising companies and creating national champions. And young
economists in the World Bank and other multilateral institutions have begun to
discuss embracing a new industrial policy.
That raises some tricky questions about the
global economic system. How can you ensure a fair trading system if some
companies enjoy the support, overt or covert, of a national government? How can
you prevent governments from using companies as instruments of military power?
And how can you prevent legitimate worries about fairness from shading into
xenophobia and protectionism? Some of the biggest trade rows in recent
years—for example, over the China National Offshore Oil Corporation’s attempt
to buy America’s Unocal in 2005, and over Dubai Ports’ purchase of several
American ports—have involved state-owned enterprises. There are likely to be
many more in the future.
The rise of state capitalism is also undoing
many of the assumptions about the effects of globalisation. Kenichi Ohmae said
the nation state was finished. Thomas Friedman argued that governments had to
don the golden straitjacket of market discipline. Naomi Klein pointed out that
the world’s biggest companies were bigger than many countries. And Francis
Fukuyama asserted that history had ended with the triumph of democratic
capitalism. Now across much of the world the state is trumping the market and
autocracy is triumphing over democracy.
Ian Bremmer, the president of Eurasia Group, a
political-risk consultancy, claims that this is “the end of the free market” in
his excellent book of that title. He exaggerates. But he is right that a
striking number of governments, particularly in the emerging world, are
learning how to use the market to promote political ends. The invisible hand of
the market is giving way to the visible, and often authoritarian, hand of state
capitalism.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
Something old, something new
A brief history of state capitalism
Jan 21st 2012 | from the print edition
IN SEPTEMBER 1789 George Washington appointed
Alexander Hamilton as America’s first ever treasury secretary. Two years later
Hamilton presented Congress with a “Report on Manufactures”, his plan to get
the young country’s economy going and provide the underpinnings for its
hard-fought independence. Hamilton had no time for Adam Smith’s ideas about the
hidden hand. America needed to protect its infant industries with tariffs if it
wanted to see them grow up.
State capitalism has been around for almost as
long as capitalism itself. Anglo-Saxons like to think of themselves as the
perennial defenders of free-market orthodoxy against continental European and
Asian heresy. In reality every rising power has relied on the state to
kickstart growth or at least to protect fragile industries. Even Britain, the
crucible of free-trade thinking, created a giant national champion in the form
of the East India Company.
The appetite for industrial policy grew with
the eating, and after the second world war intervention became a mark of
civilisation as well as common sense. The Europeans created industrial
powerhouses and welfare states. The Asians poured resources into national
champions.
This long era of state activism has left a
surprisingly powerful legacy, despite the more recent fashion for privatisation
and deregulation. The rich world still has a large number of state-owned or
state-dominated companies. For example, France owns 85% of EDF, an energy
company; Japan 50% of Japan Tobacco; and Germany 32% of Deutsche Telekom. These
numbers add up: across the OECD state-owned enterprises have a combined value
of almost $2 trillion and employ 6m people.
The new kind of state capitalism started in
Singapore. Lee Kuan Yew, its founding father, was prime minister for more than
30 years and a tireless advocate of “Asian values”, by which he meant a mixture
of family values and authoritarianism. He rivalled Beatrice Webb in his faith
in the wisdom of the state. But he also grasped that Singapore’s best chance
lay in attracting the world’s most powerful corporations, though he rejected
the laissez-faire ideas that flourished in Asia’s other great port city, Hong
Kong.
Singapore could easily have remained a tiny
oddity but for a succession of earth-shaking events. The first was the oil
embargo imposed by the Arab petrostates in the wake of the 1973 Yom Kippur war,
quadrupling the price of oil and shifting the balance of power in the world
economy. Arab governments tightened their control over the newly valuable oil
companies and amassed growing financial surpluses. For them the economic shock
was proof of the power of their oil weapon. For the Chinese it demonstrated the
importance of securing a safe supply of oil and other raw materials.
The second event was Deng Xiaoping’s
transformation of China. Deng borrowed heavily from the Singaporean model. He
embraced globalisation by creating special economic zones and inviting foreign
companies in. He espoused corporatism by forcing state enterprises to model
themselves on Western companies. And he concentrated resources on national
champions and investment in research and development. By doing all this, he
plugged 1.3 billion people into the world economy.
The final event was the collapse of Soviet
communism. This was initially seen as one of the great triumphs of liberalism,
but it soon unleashed dark forces. Communist apparatchiks-turned-oligarchs
grabbed chunks of the economy. Between 1990 and 1995 the country’s GDP dropped
by a third. Male life expectancy shrank from 64 to 58. Once-captive nations
broke away. In 1998 the country defaulted on its debts.
The post-Soviet disaster created a craving for
order. Vladimir Putin, then Russia’s president, reasserted direct state control
over “strategic” industries and brought the remaining private-sector oligarchs
to heel. But just as important as the backlash in Russia was the one in China.
The collapse of the Soviet Union confirmed the Chinese Communist Party’s
deepest fear: that the end of party rule would mean the breakdown of order. The
only safe way forward was a judicious mixture of private enterprise and state
capitalism.
------------------------------------------
State capitalism’s global reach
New masters of the universe
How state enterprise is spreading
Jan 21st 2012 | from the print edition
THE HEADQUARTERS OF China Central Television,
designed by Rem Koolhaas, a Dutch architect, looks like a monstrous space
invader striding across Beijing. The headquarters of the China National
Offshore Oil Corporation resembles an oil tanker emerging from a shimmering
sea. It was designed by Kohn Pedersen Fox, an international firm of architects,
and sits directly opposite China’s ministry of foreign affairs. All over
central Beijing you see state companies erecting giant monuments to themselves,
reflecting their huge power and their vision of themselves as agents of
modernisation.
That vision is not confined to Beijing.
Petronas, Malaysia’s state-owned oil company, has built 88-storey twin towers
in the heart of Kuala Lumpur. In Moscow, VTB, Russia's second-largest state
bank, has its headquarters in a sleek glass skyscraper in the spanking new
Moskva City Business Complex.
The most striking thing about state-owned
enterprises (SOEs) is their sheer collective might in the emerging world. They
make up most of the market capitalisation of China’s and Russia’s stockmarkets
and account for 28 of the emerging world’s 100 biggest companies. True, the
state-owned sector as a whole has been in rapid retreat. It now makes up only
about a third of China’s and Russia’s GDP, against almost all of it two decades
ago. But this decline is the result of selective pruning rather than
liberalisation. Governments have been letting go of the small in order to
strengthen their hold over the large.
This has resulted in a couple of paradoxes. The
SOEs are becoming wealthier and more powerful even as the overall state sector
shrinks, and governments are tightening their grip on the commanding heights of
the economy even as the private sector grows. The concentration of power in an
inner circle of SOEs has been gathering pace over the past decade: China’s 121
biggest SOEs, for example, saw their total assets increase from $360 billion in
2002 to $2.9 trillion in 2010 (though their share of GDP has declined). And it
has been given an extra boost by the 2007-08 financial crisis: in 2009 some 85%
of China’s $1.4 trillion in bank loans went to state companies.
Governments are becoming more sophisticated
owners. Only a handful of SOEs are still reporting directly to government
ministries. Most governments prefer to exercise control through their ownership
of shares: they have become the most powerful shareholders across much of the
developing world from China to Thailand and from Russia to Saudi Arabia.
Sometimes they hold all the shares, particularly in oil companies like
Malaysia’s Petronas, transport firms like China’s Ocean Shipping Company and
quasi-military outfits like Russia’s United Aircraft Corporation. But
increasingly they prefer to dilute their shareholdings. The United Nations
Conference on Trade and Development defines a state-owned company as one in
which the state owns more than 10% of the shares. Some governments have
mastered the art of controlling companies through minority stakes: in Russia,
for example, the state has retained golden shares in 181 firms.
State enterprises have become more productive,
thanks to a mixture of judicious pruning and relentless restructuring. In China
their return on assets increased from 0.7% in 1998 to 6.3% in 2006 (though some
say the figures are misleading). They have also become more international:
companies that once served only their domestic market, such as Baosteel and
Shanghai Electric, are striding onto the global stage. These three
developments—more sophisticated methods of control, more productive use of
assets and rapid globalisation—are going hand in hand.
The hard core of the state-owned sector are the
national oil companies: the 13 giants that control more than three-quarters of
the world’s oil supplies. Governments continue to keep a heavy hand on this
industry. The Chinese state owns 90% of the shares in PetroChina and 80% of
those in Sinopec. Even so, the national oil companies are being transformed by
the same forces that are transforming the state-owned sector in general.
A few companies preserve the great tradition of
state-sponsored incompetence and overmanning. Venezuela’s Petróleos de
Venezuela, which is central to the patronage machine of the country’s
president, Hugo Chávez, is an obvious example. More surprisingly, so is
Mexico’s Pemex, which has successfully resisted numerous attempts to reform it.
Malaysia’s Petronas has improved dramatically over the past five years. Saudi
Arabia’s Aramco, which controls more than a tenth of the world’s oil and with
it the fate of the world economy, is almost as well managed as private-sector
oil companies such as Exxon Mobil. The Saudi monarchy has slimmed the company’s
workforce, brought in professional managers, contracted out ancillary work and
formed alliances with international companies.
The
world is their oyster
More generally, national energy companies are
no longer content just to sit at home and pump the oil or gas. They are
increasingly venturing abroad in order to lock up future energy supplies or
forming alliances with private-sector specialists to increase their access to
expertise and ideas. Gazprom has been buying up oil and gas companies across
eastern Europe and Asia. In 2008 it bought a 51% stake in Naftna Industrija
Srbije, a Serbian energy giant. Chinese oil companies have been striking deals
across Africa: in 2006 Sinopec bought a huge Angolan oil well for $692m. The
multiplying alliances between national and international companies are not
always successful: BP, for example, will not rush into any future deals with
Russia’s Rosneft. But they are plugging national energy companies into the
global market for people and ideas and closing the gap between the state-run
and the private sector.
State capitalism also has a collection of
companies that sit at the opposite end of the ownership scale from national
energy companies: national champions that formally are privately owned but
enjoy a huge amount of either overt or covert support from their respective
governments. Sometimes such governments prefer to exercise their patronage at
arm’s length because they have little experience of the sector; this is often
true of the IT industry in China. Sometimes they offer their patronage to a
private company after it has become a winner. Either way the end result is the
creation of a new class of state companies: national champions that may not be
owned by governments but are nevertheless closely linked to them.
China’s Lenovo likes to think of itself as a
private-sector computer company, but the Chinese Academy of Sciences provided
it with seed money (and still owns lots of shares), and the government has
repeatedly stepped in to smooth its growth, not least when it acquired IBM’s
personal-computer division for $1.25 billion in 2004. Brazil’s Vale also
considers itself a private-sector mining company, but the government treats it
as a national champion and recently forced its boss, Roger Agnelli, to step
aside because it did not like his plans to sack workers. There is a long list
of national champions that operate in the shadow of the state, including
China’s Geely in cars, Huawei in telecoms equipment and Haier in white goods.
The
wealth of nations
State capitalists are not just running
companies; they are also managing huge pools of capital in the form of
sovereign-wealth funds (SWFs). Leviathan is becoming a finance capitalist as
well as a captain of industry.
The sovereign-wealth business was pioneered
decades ago by the petrostates and by Singapore. The Kuwait Investment
Authority was set up in 1953. But more recently the business has been
turbocharged by two developments: the surge in energy prices and China’s
accumulation of a vast current-account surplus. Today’s SWFs account for some
of the world’s biggest pools of capital. The Abu Dhabi Investment Authority
controls $627 billion, putting it in the same league as some of the largest
American mutual funds. Saudi Arabia’s SAMA foreign-holdings company in December
2011 controlled $473 billion, China’s SAFE Investment Company $568 billion and
China Investment Corporation $410 billion. In all, the world’s sovereign-wealth
funds control about $4.8 trillion in assets, a figure that is likely to rise to
$10 trillion by the end of this decade.
Sovereign-wealth funds come in two varieties:
“savings” funds intended to find productive homes for investments, and
“development” funds that also promote economic development. China Investment
Corporation has focused on producing a portfolio of financial assets, for
example, whereas Abu Dhabi’s various investment funds have been more interested
in funding the region’s economic development to prepare for the day when the
oil runs out. In 2008 Abu Dhabi created a fund that specialises in investing in
high-tech companies, both at home and abroad. In its first big deal it formed
an alliance with Advanced Micro Devices, an American chipmaker, to create a
local semiconductor manufacturer, GLOBALFOUNDRIES.
The financial crisis of 2007-08 shifted the
argument in favour of the second kind of fund. Soon after China Investment
Corporation was set up in September 2007 it saw the money it had put into
American investment banks turn to ashes. Petrostate SWFs have increased their
emphasis on investing in science and research. Sovereign-wealth funds in
Kuwait, Qatar, Russia, China, Kazakhstan and Ireland have been asked to support
domestic financial institutions. Almost all funds are taking a more active
interest in the way the companies they own are managed, for example by
demanding a seat on the board.
Nasser Saidi, chief economist of the Dubai
International Financial Centre, argues that the rise of the emerging world will
inevitably force the global financial system to change, from a hub-and-spokes
model (with London and New York acting as the hubs) to a spider’s-web model of
many interconnected hubs. The 2007-08 crisis has dramatically speeded up this
process: SWFs now like to do much of their business with each other rather than
going through rich-world intermediaries. In 2009 China Investment Corporation
and the Qatar Investment Authority signed a joint-venture agreement. In the
following year a consortium of nine funds, including the Government of
Singapore’s Investment Corporation, China Investment Corporation and the Abu
Dhabi Investment Council, invested $1.8 billion in BTG Pactual, a Brazilian
investment bank spun off from UBS, a Swiss bank.
It is possible for a country to have any or all
of these institutions in place without being a member of the state-capitalist
club. Norway boasts the world’s 13th-biggest oil company by revenue, Statoil,
and its third-biggest sovereign-wealth fund, the Government Pension Fund, with
$560 billion in assets, but requires both of them to behave like regular
companies. These various elements can also be put together in a variety of
ways. The next section will look at some of the different forms that state
capitalism can take.
------------------------------------------------------------
A choice of models
Theme and variations
State capitalism is not all the same
Jan 21st 2012 | from the print edition
·
·
IT IS EASY for a casual visitor to China to be
fooled into thinking that he is in a normal capitalist country. The big cities
are dotted with Starbucks and Kinkos. The newspapers run stories about small
businesspeople falling prey to loan sharks. Business executives are whisked
around in Mercedes cars with blackened windows. Their wives and mistresses idle
their afternoons away in doga classes—yoga that includes the pet dog.
But the form of capitalism on display is highly
idiosyncratic. Company bosses are routinely moved to rival companies without
any explanation. Company headquarters have space set aside for representatives
of the armed forces. And the deeper you look, the queerer things become. In his
indispensable book, “The Party”, Richard McGregor points out that the bosses of
China’s 50-odd leading companies all have a “red machine” sitting next to their
Bloomberg terminals and family photographs that provides an instant (and
encrypted) link to the Communist Party’s high command.
What might be called “the party state”
exercises a degree of control over the economy that is unparalleled in the rest
of the state-capitalist world. The party has cells in most big companies—in the
private as well as the state-owned sector—complete with their own offices and
files on employees. It controls the appointment of captains of industry and, in
the SOEs, even corporate dogsbodies. It holds meetings that shadow formal board
meetings and often trump their decisions, particularly on staff appointments.
It often gets involved in business planning and works with management to
control workers’ pay.
The party state exercises power through two
institutions: the State-Owned Assets Supervision and Administration Commission
(SASAC) and the Communist Party’s Organisation Department. SASAC, which holds
shares in the biggest companies, is the world’s largest controlling shareholder
and the state-capitalist institution par excellence. It has been spearheading
the policy of creating national champions by consolidating and pruning its
portfolio: the number of companies under its supervision has declined from 198
in 2003 to 121 today. It has also been implementing the party’s policy of
creating a “harmonious society” by regulating pay. In 2009 the average SOE boss
earned $88,000 and the highest-paid, the chairman of China Mobile, $182,000.
High pay in SOEs has been a big source of disharmony.
SASAC can be
something of a paper tiger. It has been trying for years to force the SOEs to
pay higher dividends to the government, with only limited success. Similarly,
nobody believes that the SOE bosses’ nominal pay bears any relation to their
real remuneration. However, nobody would apply the term “paper tiger” to the
Organisation Department. Created by Chairman Mao in 1924, it has become the
world’s mightiest human-resources department. It appoints all the senior
figures in China Inc. In 2004 it reshuffled the heads of the three biggest
telecoms companies. In 2009 it rotated the bosses of the three biggest airlines.
In 2010 it did the same to the chiefs of the three biggest oil companies, each
of which is aFortune 500
company. Even the most successful top executives of China’s SOEs are cadres
first and company men second. They care more about pleasing their party bosses
than about the global market.
The party state has reinforced its power by
creating “vertical” business groups. In most emerging markets (including Hong
Kong next door) business groups are “horizontal”: companies sprawl into
adjacent businesses—telecoms companies into hotels, shipping companies into
property—in order to exploit their local connections. In China business groups
focus on particular industries. The party state encourages companies to band
together into industry clusters by giving them preferential access to contracts
and stockmarket listings. It also encourages them to establish subdivisions
such as a domestic holding company, a finance company, a research institute and
a foreign division. SASAC typically owns 100% of the shares in the holding
company. The holding company in turn owns a smaller proportion of shares—say
60%—in the foreign division. This makes it possible for business groups to
present lots of different faces—for instance, an inward-looking one in the form
of the holding company and an outward-looking one in the form of the
international division. It also allows the party state to exercise control of
an entire chain of companies. Thus PetroChina might look like a regular Western
company, with a listing on the New York Stock Exchange. But in fact it is the
international division of a huge group called China National Petroleum
Corporation, the foreign head of a dragon whose body and raison d’être lie in
Beijing.
The
Kremlin as capitalist-in-chief
In Russia the past decade has seen a remarkable
strengthening of the power of the state, which during Boris Yeltsin’s period of
“wild privatisation” looked as if it might crumble. The Kremlin has turned
scattered companies into national champions. Aeroflot reabsorbed regional
airlines spun off in the 1990s. Russian Technologies rolled up hundreds of
state companies, many of which had little to do with technology, into a vast
conglomerate. The government has also renationalised industries that were
privatised in the 1990s. Rosneft, an oil company, took over most of Yukos from
Mikhail Khodorkovsky, once Russia’s richest man, and Gazprom bought Sibneft
from Roman Abramovich.
As a result the Russian state once again
controls the commanding heights of the economy—only this time through share
ownership rather than directly. The state holds huge chunks of the shares of
the country’s biggest and most strategic companies, including Transneft, a
pipeline company; Sukhoi, an aircraft-maker; Rosneft; Sberbank; Unified Energy
Systems, an electricity giant; Aeroflot; and Gazprom.
The Kremlin has also established control over
Russia’s oligarchs, reducing once-mighty rottweilers to shivering chihuahuas
and transforming supposedly private companies into organs of the state. The
brutal persecution and imprisonment of Mr Khodorkovsky helped to instil
obedience, and periodically the state waves a bloody stick at the oligarchs to
keep them in their place. They dutifully pick up the tab for public works (such
as the 2014 Winter Olympics) and keep out of politics.
The private-sector oligarchs have been replaced
at the heart of the economy by state-sector bureaugarchs, most of them former
KGB officials who have close ties with Vladimir Putin and have spent the past
decade steadily accumulating power (though not personal stakes in the
businesses). Mr Putin, currently the prime minister, is chairman of the
supervisory board of Vnesheconombank, a state development bank. Igor Sechin,
the deputy prime minister, was chairman of Rosneft until Dmitry Medvedev,
Russia’s president, ordered government ministers to step down as chairmen of
state companies’ boards of directors last year to tidy things up. Such people
form the board of Russia Inc, a company that is headed by Mr Putin, dominated
by the KGB and dedicated to controlling the country’s most lucrative assets,
from oil and gas to nuclear power, diamonds, metals, arms, aviation and
transport.
These varieties of state capitalism
all have one thing in common: politicians have far more power than they do
under liberal capitalism
The result is a highly unusual form of
capitalism, dominated by a handful of gigantic firms and controlled by a clique
of security officials. Two state-controlled companies, Sberbank and Gazprom,
account for more than half of the turnover of the Russian stock exchange.
Russian capitalism would have been concentrated even if the Kremlin had not
been so ruthless. Oil and gas companies, which account for 20% of the country’s
GDP and 60% of its exports, thrive on economies of scale and scope. Poor
infrastructure encourages vertical integration; for example, metal companies
have been buying ports to ensure that they can get their goods out on time.
Still, having so much political power in so few hands has enormously increased
this concentration.
This quintessentially Russian form of state
capitalism has nevertheless been embracing the global market. Oil and gas
companies have been buying similar firms abroad or listing on foreign stock
exchanges. In July 2006 Rosneft raised $11 billion by selling 15% of its shares
on the London stock exchange. Russia’s sovereign-wealth funds have been
particularly keen on buying foreign companies, in part because Russia’s own
business practices are so murky. And Russian businesspeople have bought lots of
property abroad, particularly in London.
Petrostate
capitalism
Oil and water may not mix, but oil and royalty
mix very well to create petrostate capitalism. Middle Eastern monarchs have
been using oil to keep themselves in funds for decades. But these days some of
them are taking a remarkably sophisticated approach to managing their
economies, embracing professional management.
The al-Maktoums, who rule Dubai, created Dubai
World, a huge state-owned holding company, to run their projects. The Saudis
have handed the day-to-day management of their biggest companies, Saudi Aramco
and Saudi Basic Industries, to professional managers. The petro-royals have
also become enthusiastic practitioners of state-sponsored modernisation. The
al-Maktoums have been trendsetters because they never had much oil to begin
with. It now accounts for under 5% of the emirate’s GDP. They have provided
Dubai with a world-class airport, an important financial hub and a scattering
of “knowledge villages” and “silicon centres”. Even conservative Saudi Arabia
claims to be building four tech-enabled cities.
But the Gulf model of modernisation from above
has been plagued by two familiar curses, cronyism and bubbles. There is only so
much that professional managers can do to prevent the local royals from
damaging the region’s companies. Bahrain’s Gulf Air and Kuwait Airways have
been albatrosses. Dubai World accumulated $80 billion in debt building the
world’s tallest skyscraper and a palm-shaped artificial island. The state of
Dubai had to be rescued by neighbouring Abu Dhabi.
The problems of cronyism and corruption have
proved even more toxic in other parts of the Middle East. In Egypt Hosni
Mubarak, the president until the Arab spring, handed the management of the
state companies to incompetent people while making sure his cronies did well
out of privatisation. In Algeria SOEs are notorious dens of patronage and
typically run at only 50% of capacity. In Syria the overwhelming majority of
the country’s top 250 SOEs have been in the red for many years.
Leviathan
as a minority investor
Brazil is the most ambiguous member of the
state-capitalist camp: a democracy that also embraces many of the features of
Anglo-Saxon capitalism. But it is worth examining for two reasons. First, it is
a weather vane for state capitalism, a leading privatiser in the 1990s that is
now forcing its biggest mining company, Vale, to keep workers it does not need,
and obliging a bunch of smaller companies to embark on subsidised
consolidation. And second, it has invented one of the sharpest new tools in the
state-capitalist toolbox.
Brazil has spent most of its modern history in
pursuit of state-driven modernisation. A survey in the early 1980s showed that
it had more than 500 SOEs. Brazil launched a privatisation drive in the 1990s
to deal with hyperinflation, surging deficits and general sclerosis. But more
recently it has moved in a new direction. The government has poured resources
into a handful of state champions, particularly in natural resources and
telecoms. It has also produced a new model of industrial policy: replacing
direct with indirect government ownership through the Brazilian National
Development Bank (BNDES) and its investment subsidiary (BNDESPar); and swapping
majority for minority ownership by acquiring shares in a broad spectrum of
different companies. Sergio Lazzarini, of Brazil’s Insper Institute of
Education and Research, and Aldo Musacchio, of Harvard Business School, have
christened this model “Leviathan as a minority shareholder”.
This minority-shareholder model has several advantages.
It limits the state’s ability to use SOEs to reward clients or to pursue social
policies. Private shareholders have just enough power to kick up a fuss. But it
also gives the state more influence for its money. By 2009 BNDESPar’s holdings
were worth $53 billion, or just 4% of the stockmarket. Yet the state spoke with
a loud voice across corporate Brazil. Messrs Lazzarini and Musacchio have also
shown, in a detailed study of 296 firms traded on the São Paulo stock exchange
between 1995 and 2003, that this model can increase firms’ returns on their
assets. Brazilian companies typically underinvest in productivity-boosting
equipment because the capital markets are so underdeveloped. State holdings
provide them with money that they cannot get elsewhere.
Yet this clever version of state capitalism is
currently in danger of overreaching itself. Petrobras’s discovery, in November
2007, of huge deposits of oil buried deep beneath the Atlantic seabed has
filled politicians’ heads with dreams of grand projects. The shift in the
world’s balance of power from America to China has also helped to persuade many
Brazilians that the future lies with state capitalism. The result has been a
burst of unwise interventionism. The government is trying to force Petrobras to
use expensive local equipment suppliers despite doubts about their competence.
It removed Roger Agnelli from his post as CEO of Vale despite his outstanding
record. It has also taken to creating national champions through forced
mergers: BRF (Sadia and Perdigão) in the food sector; Oi (which was made to buy
Brasil Telecom) in telecoms; Fibria (VCP and Arucruz) in pulp and paper. Even
the most sophisticated models of state capitalism are not safe from
over-zealous politicians.
The new
elite
These varieties of state capitalism all have
one thing in common: politicians have far more power than they do under liberal
capitalism. In authoritarian regimes they can restructure entire industries at
the stroke of a pen. Even in democratic ones like Brazil they can tell the
biggest companies what to do. In China party hacks can find themselves running
the country’s biggest companies (and SOE bosses sometimes get big jobs in the
party). In Russia they may be running the biggest companies while also sitting
in the cabinet. But there are nevertheless limits to Leviathan’s power.
State-owned enterprises often have a good deal
of operational freedom. Edward Steinfeld, a professor at the Massachusetts
Institute of Technology who spent many years serving on the board of China
National Offshore Oil Corporation, recalls that the company’s relationship with
its political bosses had “less to do with rigid top-down control than with
mixed signals, ambiguity and even outright silence”.
Such enterprises can also wield a lot of
influence over their supposed political masters. China’s SOEs have successfully
frustrated attempts to make them pay more dividends. State-owned energy
companies arguably have more influence over energy policy in state-capitalist
countries than private energy companies have in liberal countries. Over a drink
Russians will happily speculate about whether the Kremlin runs Gazprom or
Gazprom runs the Kremlin.
State-owned
enterprises are also producing a more sophisticated generation of managers:
people who have learned about business in the world’s best business schools,
who have worked abroad and have a far less blinkered view of the world than
their predecessors. Katherine Xin, of China Europe International Business
School (CEIBS) in Shanghai, says that many SOEs want their managers to have a
world-class business education. Baosteel has been sending its senior managers
on executive MBA courses for more than a decade. It also brings in academics
from Switzerland’s IMD business school to provide tailor-made courses. CNPC has
been sending high-flyers to get MBAs in America since 1999. Ms Xin points out
that the Chinese version of the Harvard Business Review is a must-read in the upper echelons
of state-owned companies.
Members of this new generation of managers are
changing the management of the public sector, too, as they alternate between
the corporate domain and government. There are currently 17 prominent Chinese
political leaders who have held senior positions in large SOEs. Conversely, 27
prominent business leaders are serving on the party’s Central Committee. If
state capitalism allows politicians to shape companies, it also allows
companies to shape politicians.
-----------------------------------------------------
Pros and cons
Mixed bag
SOEs are good at infrastructure projects, not so good at innovation
Jan 21st 2012 | from the print edition
THE HIGH-SPEED train journey from Beijing to
Shanghai is a revelation to a visitor used to Britain’s dilapidated railway
system. Young women in neat red uniforms take pity on a foreigner and guide him
to his seat. The train quickly accelerates to its cruising speed of 300km an
hour and reaches Shanghai, 1,318km (820 miles) away, in under five hours. The
new station there is a festival of sweeping curves.
The feeling of travelling so fast for so long
is disconcerting. The countryside whizzes by in a blur, though the ride is
impeccably smooth. Even more disconcerting for a Westerner is the feeling that
he is being left in the dust. This is no prestige project for the Chinese
elite. The queue to get on the train is more like a scrum. The smell of last
night’s alcohol hangs in the air. For many Chinese people high-speed trains are
becoming a normal convenience.
A visit to the headquarters of Russian Railways
can feel a bit like a voyage back in time. The guards wear the peaked hats and
gruff manners of the Soviet era. A display shows the children of railway
workers triumphing in chess and athletics. Vladimir Yakunin, the company’s
boss, started his career with the KGB. He concedes that his company is a giant
of an organisation: it has 1.2m employees, 20,000 stations, 86,000km of track,
a network of schools and health clinics and even an equestrian school. He also
agrees that the state’s influence is all-pervasive. Three white telephones next
to his desk provide him with direct access to the Kremlin (he says he has a
separate line to his old friend, Mr Putin). He cannot even sell one of the
chairs that surround his vast table without the government’s permission.
Yet Mr Yakunin is a dynamo of a man who has
changed recruitment policies to attract high-flyers, introduced total quality
management and brought in Ernst & Young, an international firm of accountants,
to audit the books. He also points out that some of the oddities of his
company, such as its schools and clinics, have been around for a century and
derive from the difficulties of running a railway in the middle of nowhere.
There is no such thing as pure capitalism or pure socialism, he argues; only
more or less sensible solutions to practical problems.
Not as
simple as it looks
State capitalists like to set China’s recent
successes against America’s mounting failures. They add that Uncle Sam was quick
to nationalise General Motors when it needed to. Anti-state capitalists argue
that Russia is a Potemkin village and China a paper tiger. For instance,
China’s high-speed rail looked less wonderful last year when 39 people were
killed and about 200 injured in a collision in China’s eastern Zhejiang
province, after which maximum speeds were reduced across the country.
A balanced assessment of state capitalism has
to allow for three caveats. The first is that there is no clear dividing line
between state-owned and private companies. “Private” champions such as Huawei,
the telecoms giant, have repeatedly been given government help. This makes it
hard to produce precise calculations about the productivity of the two sectors.
Second, ownership is not the only thing in play. Some of the problems, and the
successes, of state capitalism have more to do with rapid development than with
state ownership. Third, everything depends on context. It is quite possible for
state capitalism to work well in some areas (eg, infrastructure) and badly in
others (eg, consumer goods). It is also possible for it to boost growth at one
stage of development and impede it at another.
State capitalism’s most obvious achievements
are in infrastructure. China has produced a large number of world
infrastructure records, such as the largest hydroelectric project, the Three
Gorges dam, and 6,400km of high-speed rail. It has also scattered new airports
and railway terminals across the land. Even Russia’s more rough-and-ready
railway system works pretty well, despite punishing weather.
BCG, a consultancy, argues that this
infrastructure boom will continue for some time yet. Over the next 20 years the
BRIC countries will account for more than half of the growth in road travel and
more than 40% of the growth in air travel. The consultancy also points out that
state institutions are well placed to feed this boom. Sovereign-wealth funds
are favouring infrastructure projects to avoid the volatility of the
stockmarket. Chinese companies are building roads and railways in Africa, power
plants and bridges in South-East Asia and schools and bridges in America. In
the most recent list of the world’s biggest global contractors, compiled by an
industry newsletter, Chinese companies held four of the top five positions.
China State Construction Engineering Corporation has undertaken more than 5,000
projects in about 100 different countries and earned $22.4 billion in revenues
in 2009. China’s Sinohydro controls more than half the world’s market for
building hydro power stations.
State capitalism has also enjoyed some success
in tackling second-generation infrastructure problems such as building the
information superhighway and mandating higher environmental standards. China’s
mobile-phone network is the world’s largest, yet it suffers from fewer dropped
calls or areas with no signal than America’s. China has the world’s biggest
number of internet users, 420m, of whom 364m have broadband. It has also turned
itself into a pioneer in some areas of green energy: it is the world’s largest
exporter of solar panels, for example. Big bets on green technology can easily turn
into big mistakes. But generally infrastructure belongs on the positive side of
the ledger.
It is quite possible for state
capitalism to work well in some areas (eg, infrastructure) and badly in others
(eg, consumer goods)
State capitalism has
also been successful at producing national champions that can compete globally.
Two-thirds of emerging-market companies that made it onto the Fortune 500
list are state-owned, and most of the rest enjoy state largesse of one sort or
another. Governments can provide companies with the resources that they need to
reach global markets. They can also insist on mergers that produce global
giants.
The obsession with national champions can be
dangerous: mating two dinosaurs seldom produces a gazelle. But champions have
their uses. They can boost national pride, they can ensure that local companies
can compete for the best and the brightest with foreign multinationals and they
can help emerging countries to establish global standards rather than playing
by other people’s rules. The Chinese are determined to do this with the growing
market for the “internet of things”.
The most interesting argument in favour of
state capitalism is that it makes it easier for emerging countries to learn
from the rest of the world. National champions are the corporate world’s
greatest learning machines. To produce them you need to study the best of the
breed. And once you have them you can deepen your learning still further—by
listing them on foreign exchanges (which introduces you to the world’s sharpest
bankers and analysts), or by taking over foreign companies (which can provide
you with rare expertise). China’s Geely International got access to some of the
world’s most advanced carmaking skills when it took over Volvo for $1.8
billion. Shanghai Electric Group enriched its engineering knowledge by buying
Goss International for $1.5 billion and forming joint ventures with Siemens and
Mitsubishi. Saudi Basic Industries Corporation has become more cosmopolitan by
purchasing companies in dozens of countries.
All this success is producing much
I-have-seen-the-future-and-it works euphoria. The bosses of state industries
like to argue that they have the best of both worlds—the ability to plan for
the future but also to respond to fast-changing consumer tastes. Even outsiders
can sound giddy. Ms Xin of CEIBS points out that the best state companies are
infinitely better than their predecessors just five years ago. China Mobile,
she says, is as good as almost any of its rivals in the West. Edmund Tse, of Booz
& Company, argues that the system is much more flexible than it looks at
first sight.
In October 2007 China’s president, Hu Jintao,
unveiled his highest priority for the future at the 17th National Congress of
the Communist Party in the Great Hall of the People: improving the country’s
“capacity for independent innovation”. China had already been working hard at
this. The government had invited Western champions such as Microsoft and Google
to establish research facilities, instructed domestic champions to be more
innovative and poured money into science and technology clusters (Beijing’s
Zhongguancun Science Park was already home to nearly 20,000 high-tech
enterprises as Mr Hu spoke). But it needed to redouble its efforts in the
future.
Other state-capitalist countries are equally
keen on independent innovation. The Russian elite is excited about Skolkovo, a
high-tech park-cum-enterprise-zone just outside Moscow. Skolkovo is supposed to
act as a factory for indigenous technologists and entrepreneurs, a magnet for
foreign multinationals, an inspiration for young people, an insurance policy
against over-reliance on energy and a bridge between the scientific and the
business worlds. Dubai contains a knowledge village, a media city, an IT
corridor and a huge finance centre.
The
downsides
Yet the odds on any of these efforts succeeding
are low. Governments are good at providing the seedcorn for innovation:
America’s, for instance, provided some of the funding for Stanford University
and even helped to found the first venture-capital company. But they are bad at
turning seedcorn into bread. Josh Lerner, of Harvard Business School, describes
state-sponsored innovation as a “boulevard of broken dreams”, a term more often
applied to the entertainment industry. Malaysia’s $150m BioValley, which opened
in 2005, is now known as the “Valley of the Bio Ghosts”. Dubai has produced
more red ink than new products. The architects of Skolkovo worry that Dmitry
Medvedev’s impending retirement from the presidency will doom their project
before they have opened the first building.
Dan Breznitz and Michael Murphee, of the
Georgia Institute of Technology, argue that the pursuit of indigenous
innovation could prove to be a distraction. Foxconn, a huge
Taiwanese-registered electronics group, has an unrivalled ability to
mass-produce iPads and the like; it employs 270,000 people in its factory
complex in Shenzhen. Huawei is a master of improving on other people’s
technology and bringing it to market at lightning speed. China’s Pearl River
delta is swimming with small companies that dominate tiny market niches.
China’s universities mass-produce graduates in disciplines that have been
forgotten in the West, such as mining and heavy engineering. China would be
better off exploiting these advantages rather than trying to build the next
Silicon Valley.
Of
productivity and power
There is striking evidence that state-owned
companies are not only less innovative but also less productive than their
private competitors. The Beijing-based Unirule Institute of Economics argues
that, allowing for all the hidden subsidies such as free land, the average real
return on equity for state-owned companies between 2001 and 2009 was -1.47%.
Older studies suggest that productivity decreases with every step away from
100% private to 100% state-owned. An OECD paper in 2005 noted that the total
factor productivity of private companies is twice that of state companies. And
a study by the McKinsey Global Institute in the same year found that companies
in which the state holds a minority stake are 70% more productive than wholly
state-owned ones.
But poor productivity has not stopped them from
making lots of money. In 2009 just two Chinese state-owned companies—China
Mobile and China National Petroleum Corporation—made more profits ($33 billion)
than China’s 500 most profitable private companies combined. In 2010 the top
129 Chinese SOEs made estimated net profits of $151 billion, 50% more than the
year before (in many cases helped by near-monopolies). In the first six months
of 2010 China’s four biggest state commercial banks made average profits of
$211m a day.
State companies have been gobbling up private
ones. They have also been gobbling up capital. State-owned companies in China
pay interest of only 1.6% when they borrow from state banks, but private ones
are charged 4.7%—if they can get a loan at all. In 2009 private firms accounted
for only 2% of China’s official outstanding loans. The result has been an
epidemic of bankruptcies and suicides in the private sector even as state
companies are splurging out on extravagant new headquarters.
Those state companies have a vast appetite for
talent, too. Two Chinese with recent MBA degrees explain that they chose jobs
with state-owned companies because they pay more than private ones and as much
as multinational ones and offer shorter hours and cast-iron job security. But
they were shocked by the extravagant perks and widespread corruption they
found. A Russian who is currently studying for an MBA tells remarkably similar
stories. The SOEs are recreating the old “iron rice bowl” (jobs and perks for
life) with modern materials.
Yet there is little chance that state companies
will be reformed soon. They provide comfortable berths for leading politicians
and their children and hangers-on. Institutions that are nominally owned by the
people have been taken over by ruling elites—the Communist Party in China, the
security high command in Russia and the royal families in the Arab world. The
99% who do not benefit from these arrangements are getting increasingly angry
with the 1% who do. But unlike their contemporaries in the West they have few
ways of showing it.
---------------------------------------------------------
Going abroad
The world in their hands
State capitalism looks outward as well as inward
Jan 21st 2012 | from the print edition
IT IS FITTING that China’s national symbol
should be an animal that spends 16 hours a day eating bamboo. China is an
energy panda that is obsessed by the question of where its next mouthful of
bamboo will come from. The Chinese elite sees the world in terms of brutal competition
for limited resources. And it has no truck with Western ideas about relying on
the market. (“Western countries can feel secure purchasing oil internationally
because they created the system,” says one diplomat. “China did not.”) China is
utterly convinced that it needs to use all the elements of national power—its
companies and banks, its aid agencies and diplomats—to get its rightful share.
China’s obsession with going out in search of
raw materials has been growing for almost two decades. In 1993 the country
became a net importer of oil. In 2003 it interpreted America’s invasion of Iraq
as a grab for oil. And in 2010 it became the world’s biggest consumer of
energy. This obsession has dominated foreign policy and reinforced state
capitalism. A country that had been turned inward for millennia has started
popping up everywhere, and has found that it can change the rules of the game.
An economy that had been focused on domestic growth has engaged in a flurry of
international acquisitions.
China has been striking deals across the world,
often in difficult places that are shunned by the West, in order to lock up
supplies of oil and other raw materials. It has an estimated 10,000 workers in
Sudan alone. It has provided Russia with a $25 billion export-backed loan to
help Rosneft and Transneft to supply it with 300,000 barrels per day of crude,
for example, and signed a $1.7 billion deal with Iran to develop parts of the
North Azadegan oilfields. China National Petroleum Corporation is one of only
two companies to win contracts to develop Iraq’s oilfields. And in December
Pakistan named the Industrial and Commercial Bank of China to lead a consortium
that will finance a $1.2 billion natural-gas pipeline from Iran to Pakistan.
State capitalism has been at the heart of all
this activity. State companies have funded four-fifths of the foreign direct
investment. State banks have woven a web of soft loans. And government bodies
such as Eximbank, China’s foreign-aid bank, have made no bones about their
enthusiasm for tying foreign aid to commercial advantage. One of China’s
favourite tools is oil for infrastructure. China offers to provide poor
countries with schools, hospitals and the like (usually financed by soft loans
and built by China’s infrastructure giants) in return for a guaranteed supply
of oil or some other raw material. Eximbank supplied a $2 billion low-interest
loan to help China’s oil companies build infrastructure in Angola.
The
axis of statism
Trotsky always insisted on the impossibility of
“socialism in one country”. The same logic applies to state capitalism.
State-capitalist powers inevitably look outward as well as inward. China is the
world’s biggest exporter as well as its biggest energy consumer. Russia and the
Gulf states are energy superpowers. But they are also conscious that they are
newcomers in a global market that was created by America and Europe. So they
frequently stick together, striking deals among themselves and forging ever
closer ideological links.
China and Russia have found it easier to get on
with each other as state capitalists than they ever did as communists. Over the
past decade they have increased bilateral trade, concluded a range of economic
and trade agreements and forged a new political institution in Central Asia, the
Shangai Co-operation Organisation. Energy giants such as Gazprom and PetroChina
are intertwined in various convoluted ways.
China has also
strengthened its links with the Middle East. The old Silk Road is being
rebuilt. In 2009 the Middle Kingdom became the biggest single importer of oil
from the region and the biggest single exporter of manufactured goods there.
The two biggest investors in China’s Agricultural Bank are the Qatar Investment
Authority ($2.8 billion) and the Kuwait Investment Authority ($800m). And China
is becoming a popular destination for Middle Eastern businesspeople and
tourists: every year the region sends 200,000 visitors to a single Chinese
city, Yiwu in central Zhejiang Province, to go shopping. The city does a
roaring trade in hijabs, prayer rugs and electronic Korans.
More people are also taking the road in the
other direction. The UAE is home to 200,000 Chinese, and Dubai boasts one of
the world’s biggest Chinese malls, DragonMart, built in the shape of a dragon,
with 4,000 Chinese businesses.
After King Abdullah of Saudi Arabia ascended to
the throne in 2005 his first visit abroad was not to America, his country’s
longstanding ally, but to China. President Hu, for his part, is a frequent
traveller to the Middle East.
This “axis of state capitalism” is gaining an
ideological edge as the emerging world goes from strength to strength, America
pulls in its horns, Europe implodes and the G20 takes over from the G7.
Politicians across the region feel sure they have a formula that can combine
economic dynamism with order, taking in the best of capitalism (those sleek
modern corporations and clever wealth funds) without unleashing the havoc that
devastated Russia in the 1990s and threatened to consume America in 2007-08.
Proponents of this ideology revere Lee Kuan Yew as a founding father, see
America as a wounded giant and dismiss Europe as self-indulgent and lazy. But
they also admire Silicon Valley and Google, MIT and General Electric, Harvard
Business School and McKinsey.
The power of the axis is easily exaggerated.
The Russians resent the fact that their former junior partner in the communist
enterprise, China, has become so successful. They are also suspicious about
China’s activities in Central Asia. China, which has more than 20m Muslims,
worries that the Gulf states may export radical Islam as well as oil. Some
Africans fret about China’s enthusiasm for building roads and railways across
Africa, just as the Europeans once did. But Fu Chengyu, the chairman of China
National Offshore Oil Corporation, points out that the Chinese are rooting
around in Sudan and Angola only because the Western companies have nabbed the
best oilfields. They are adding to the global supply of oil while putting their
own people at risk (dozens of Chinese oil workers have been killed or
kidnapped).
Xenophobia plays a part, but state capitalism
is also finding it hard to evangelise. Indeed, many state capitalists are in
denial about it. Mr Putin pooh-poohs the whole idea. “If we concentrate on
certain resources, we do it only to support the industry until the companies
stand firmly,” he insists. The Chinese argue that their free-trading
credentials are as good as those of any other WTO members.
China’s ability to make huge
strategic investments, even to the point of creating entire new industries,
puts private companies at a severe disadvantage
State capitalism may not turn into a popular
movement, in the way that communism and socialism did, but it nevertheless
confronts Western policymakers with some difficult questions. How can you
ensure that business deals involving state-backed companies are fair? In 2005
CNOOC’s unsolicited bid for Unocal, one of America’s largest oil companies,
briefly shifted the American government’s attention from the Middle East to
China. Politicians thought it was a thinly disguised takeover of an American
company by the Chinese government, part of a wider plot to control the world’s
oil supplies. The House of Representatives voted 398 to 15 for a non-binding
resolution against the purchase. Six months later politicians were up in arms
again when DP World, a company owned by Dubai’s government that has ports in
almost 30 countries, tried to add six American ones to its portfolio. DP World
backed down.
Western
worries
The tensions that were on display in those
dramatic six months continue to operate. Western businesspeople are
increasingly concerned about Chinese trade policies. Two years ago the heads of
19 of America’s biggest industry associations wrote to their government to
complain about China’s “systematic efforts” to build its domestic companies “at
the expense of US firms and US intellectual property”. In July 2010 Peter
Löscher, the chief executive of Siemens, and Jürgen Hambrecht, then chairman of
BASF, personally complained to Wen Jiabao, the Chinese prime minister, about
the way that Western companies were being forced to hand over intellectual capital
in order to gain access to China’s markets. The American Chamber of Commerce in
China in its 2010 survey reported that a third of its member companies in China
felt that they were being held back by discriminatory policies.
Western policymakers are worried, too. Charlene
Barshefsky, America’s trade negotiator at the time when China’s entry into the
WTO was being considered, fears that the rise of state capitalism may be
undermining the post-war trading system. China’s ability to make huge strategic
investments, even to the point of creating entire new industries, puts private
companies at a severe disadvantage.
Peter Mandelson, a former EU trade
commissioner, thinks that “the huge and very real benefits of globalisation are
being undermined by the distorting interventions of state capitalism from one
direction and by the anxious politics of an increasingly defensive and fearful
developed world from the other.” The European Union has hinted that it may
block future takeovers of European companies by Chinese state-owned enterprises
on the ground that all SOEs are, in fact, part of a single economic entity. And
Western policymakers routinely complain that China’s refusal to let its
currency appreciate to its “natural” level is in effect subsidising China’s domestic
industry, penalising American and European companies, destroying American and
European jobs and fuelling dangerous global imbalances.
It is easy to overstate the case against state
capitalism. State capitalists harm mainly their own consumers when they
subsidise exports, and they depress their own country’s overall competitiveness
when they pour money into state champions at the expense of the rest of the
economy. But they have been playing increasingly rough in recent years: witness
China’s willingness to imprison three Rio Tinto executives for supposedly
taking bribes, and Russia’s treatment of BP. Learning to live with state
capitalism will be a serious challenge for the rest of the world.
------------------------------------------------------
The long view
And the winner is…
For all its successes, state capitalism has fatal flaws
Jan 21st 2012 | from the print edition
THE RISE OF state capitalism constitutes one of
the biggest changes in the world economy in recent years. Twenty years ago
state firms were nothing more than parts of the government machine. Ten years
ago there was widespread doubt about whether they could succeed. Today they
include some of the world’s biggest companies, sucking up profits at home and
taking on the world market with a will. Between 2005 and 2011 four of the
world’s top ten stockmarket flotations involved Chinese state companies (and
collectively raised $64.5 billion).
Is state capitalism the wave of the future, or
is it simply one in a long line of state-sponsored failures? Some commentators
have seized on the riots in Russia in December as evidence that it is already
on its way out. Others point to the continuing problems with global capitalism,
arguing that the state variety is winning the war of ideas. Andy Stern, a
former boss of the powerful Service Employees International Union, argues that
China’s economic model is superior to America’s and quotes Andy Grove, the
founder of Intel: “Our fundamental economic belief …is that the free market is
the best of all economic systems—the freer the better. Our generation has seen
the decisive victory of free-market principles over planned economies. So we
stick with this belief largely oblivious to emerging evidence that while free
markets beat planned economies, there may be room for a modification that is
even better.”
This special report has argued a different
case. State capitalism is sufficiently good at mimicking the market to ensure
it has plenty of life left in it. It is learning how to manage ideas from the
West and impose some discipline on its favoured companies. It is also putting
down ever stronger roots. There are state-capitalist banks, billionaires,
bureaucrats and even paid-up ideologues (one Chinese analyst, having listed all
of the system’s inefficiencies, says that he gives it “no more than 50 years”).
But state capitalism nevertheless suffers from
deep flaws. How can the state regulate the companies that it also runs? How can
it stop itself from throwing good money after bad? How can it remain innovative
when innovation requires the freedom to experiment? MIT’s Mr Steinfeld argues
that state capitalists are learning to play “our game” by listing their shares
and engaging in mergers and acquisitions. That, he says, makes them a
“self-obsolescing” ruling class. But state capitalists are surely playing “our
game” in order to strengthen their political positions.
The future shape of state capitalism will be
determined by two things. The first is rent-seeking on the part of the
corporate elite. Management theorists have long agonised about the
“principal-agent problem”—the tendency of managers to run companies to suit
their own interests rather than the interests of their owners or customers.
Under state capitalism this problem is as acute as anywhere. Politicians are
too distracted by other things to exercise proper oversight. Boards are weak
and disorganised. And the company’s mission tends to be a confusion of the
commercial and the social.
There are plenty of examples of good practice
for state capitalists to draw on. Singapore’s sovereign-wealth fund, Temasek,
is a model of good management. Brazil has pioneered the use of the state as a
minority shareholder. Norway has successfully shielded its sovereign-wealth
fund and state oil company from political interference. But in both China and
Russia the principal-agent problem is powerfully reinforced by the idea that
state owned companies are great sources of jobs and patronage.
Secondly, state
capitalism suffers from the misfortune that it has taken root in countries with
problematic states. China combines admirable mandarin traditions with a culture
of guanxi(connections)
and corruption. Russia has the nepotism and corruption without the mandarin
traditions. Brazil puts all the cards in the hands of insiders from both
capital and labour. Transparency International, a campaigning group, ranks
Brazil 73rd in its corruption index for 2011, with China 75th and Russia an
appalling 143rd. State capitalism often reinforces corruption because it
increases the size and range of prizes for the victors. The ruling cliques have
not only the government apparatus but also huge corporate resources at their
disposal. The People’s Bank of China estimates that between the mid-1990s and
2008 some 16,000-18,000 Chinese officials and executives at state-owned
companies made off with a total of $123 billion.
The defining battle of the 21st century will be
not between capitalism and socialism but between different versions of
capitalism. And since state capitalism is likely to be around for some time
yet, Western investors, managers and policymakers need to start thinking more
seriously about how to deal with it.
Too
visible, too strong
Investors are currently infatuated with
emerging markets because they are growing rapidly at a time when rich markets
are stagnating. But for the most part those investors are blind to the risks
posed by the excessive power of the state there. Companies are ultimately
responsible not to their private shareholders but to the government, which not
only owns the majority of the shares but also controls the regulatory and legal
system.
This creates lots of risks for investors. SOEs
typically have poorer cost controls than regular companies. They also routinely
pursue social as well as business goals. Investors can probably live with all
this because at least it is predictable. More worrying is the potential for
capriciousness. Politicians can suddenly step in and sack the senior management
or tell companies to lower their prices.
Western managers also find it hard to deal with
state-controlled firms. They tend to fall into one of two traps. Either they
treat state companies as if they were exactly the same as private ones, and get
caught out when policymakers swap company bosses around or redefine industries.
Or they treat state companies as irredeemably second-rate—and may find themselves
bought out by them or having their markets swamped.
In the past Western firms have been on the
offensive; today they are increasingly warding off emerging champions. They
used to have their pick of the best and the brightest people when they went
into emerging markets; now they have to compete with local champions that can
offer not only similar salaries but the chance to play for the home team.
CEOs in particular will have to start paying
more attention to politicians in countries with state capitalism. Over the past
30 years bosses there gained greater freedom to run their own affairs. Some of
them even began to imagine that they were “running a sovereign entity”, as
Indra Nooyi, the boss of Pepsi-Cola, has put it. But in China and Russia
ultimate sovereignty lies with the political class.
Western policymakers face even more difficult
decisions than businesspeople. They will find their voices diluted as China and
other state-capitalist countries play a more active role in multilateral
institutions. And the rise of state capitalism in the East may encourage
imitation in the West. The European Commission’s directorate for enterprise and
industry has mused on the need to create European champions to fight “unfair
competition” from overseas. Nicolas Sarkozy, the French president, has created
a French sovereign-wealth fund. Alexandre de Juniac, as chief of staff to
Christine Lagarde, then France’s finance minister, ascribed his country’s
renewed enthusiasm for dirigisme to China’s influence. Japan’s Ministry of Economy,
Trade and Industry in 2010 named the rise of state capitalism as one of the
drivers of a newly interventionist industrial strategy. Worse, the rise of
state capitalism in the East may encourage a trade war as liberal countries
attack subsidies and state-capitalist countries retaliate.
But state capitalism’s biggest failure is to do
with liberty. By turning companies into organs of the government, state
capitalism simultaneously concentrates power and corrupts it. It introduces
commercial criteria into political decisions and political decisions into
commercial ones. And it removes an essential layer of scrutiny from central
government. Robert Lowe, one of the great Victorian architects of the modern
business corporation, described businesses as “little republics” that operate
as checks and balances on the power of the big republic of government. When the
little republics and the big republic are one and the same, liberty is fatally
weakened.
Nenhum comentário:
Postar um comentário