O que é este blog?

Este blog trata basicamente de ideias, se possível inteligentes, para pessoas inteligentes. Ele também se ocupa de ideias aplicadas à política, em especial à política econômica. Ele constitui uma tentativa de manter um pensamento crítico e independente sobre livros, sobre questões culturais em geral, focando numa discussão bem informada sobre temas de relações internacionais e de política externa do Brasil. Para meus livros e ensaios ver o website: www.pralmeida.org. Para a maior parte de meus textos, ver minha página na plataforma Academia.edu, link: https://itamaraty.academia.edu/PauloRobertodeAlmeida.

Mostrando postagens com marcador inequalities. Mostrar todas as postagens
Mostrando postagens com marcador inequalities. Mostrar todas as postagens

domingo, 7 de janeiro de 2018

Aumento das desigualdades e comercio internacional: alguma relacao? NAO! - Jeffrey Frankel

A desigualdade ENTRE países está diminuindo, como já demonstraram muito tempo atrás (2002, 2006), os estudos do economista catalão (e torcedor do Barça), professor em Columbia, Xavier Sala-i-Martin, atualmente economista-chefe e responsável pelos relatórios do World Economic Forum sobre competitividade mundial.
Mas a desigualdade DENTRO dos países está aumentando, tanto nos países desenvolvidos quanto nos emergentes e em desenvolvimento, como já demonstraram vários estudos.
O que isso tem a ver com o comércio internacional? Nada, ou quase nada, como demonstra Jeffrey Frankel. Ou pouco, muito pouco.
A desigualdade aumenta com a qualificação do trabalho e com "prêmios" maiores atribuídos ao capital, relativamente ao trabalho, como diria um pikettiano. Isso é um problema? De forma nenhuma. Apenas demonstra que TODOS deveriam aumentar o seu capital intangível, o que não fizeram os preguiçosos trabalhadores não qualificados dos países avançados. Eles entraram numa "armadilha da renda média": já dispondo de uma remuneração adequada para um padrão de consumo satisfatório, passam as noites na frente da TV em lugar de continuar estudando, como todos devem fazer, para se reposicionar nos mercados de trabalho. Ser operário a vida inteira não é garantia para ninguém.
Esta é a minha "teoria" para a reconcentração de renda dentro dos países.
Portanto, não me venham com protecionismo comercial.
Ao contrário: o comércio exterior LIVRE aumenta as rendas dos cidadãos em todos os países, mesmo entre os não conectados diretamente a ele, pois permite mesmo a um desempregado comprar bens mais baratos.
Em conclusão (e aqui vale para os IDIOTAS que estão defendendo as políticas do Trump): as medidas protecionistas adotadas pelo presidente idiota vao tornar os americanos mais pobres e retirar empregos dos seus próprios eleitores.
Paulo Roberto de Almeida
São Paulo, 7/01/2018


DOES TRADE FUEL INEQUALITY?





To explain the rise in inequality that began in the 1980s and has accelerated since the turn of the century, many have pointed out that indicators of globalization, such as the trade-to-GDP ratio, have also been rising rapidly over the same period. But does that correlation imply a causal link between trade and inequality?
CAMBRIDGE – Inequality has become a major political preoccupation in the advanced economies – and for good reason. In the United States, according to the recently released World Inequality Report 2018, the share of national income claimed by the top 1% of the population rose from 11% in 1980 to 20% in 2014, compared to just 13% for the entire bottom half of the population. Qualitatively similar, though less pronounced, trends characterize other major countries such as FranceGermany, and the United Kingdom.

To explain the rise in inequality that began in the 1980s and has accelerated since the turn of the century, many have pointed out that indicators of globalization, such as the trade-to-GDP ratio, have also risen since 1980. But does that correlation imply a causal link between trade and inequality?
There are certainly reasons to doubt it. The global trade-to-GDP ratio peaked in 2008 at 61%, after a 35-year climb, falling back to 56% by 2016 – at precisely the time when fear of globalization reached political fever pitch.
What if we look at the world as a whole, rather than individual countries? As Columbia’s Xavier Sala-i-Martin pointed out in 2002 and 2006, even as inequality has risen in nearly every country, inequality across countries has decreased, owing largely to the success of developing countries like China and India in raising their per capitaincomes since the 1980s.
Multiple factors, including urbanization, high savings rates, and improved access to education, undoubtedly underlie these countries’ impressive performance. But, if one uses geography to isolate exogenous determinants of trade, it becomes apparent that trade has been among the most powerful drivers of Asia’s economic success, and thus the convergence between the developed and developing worlds.
For someone like US President Donald Trump, this would indicate that Asia’s success has come at America’s expense. This view of trade as a zero-sum game was a feature of the mercantilist theory that reigned three centuries ago, before Adam Smith and David Ricardo made the case that trade would normally benefit both partners, by enabling each to take advantage of their comparative advantages.
But the Smith-Ricardo theory has a key limitation: it does not distinguish among a country’s citizens, and therefore cannot address the question of income distribution within a country. Given this, the Heckscher-Ohlin-Stolper-Samuelson model may be more useful, as it distinguishes between workers and owners of physical, financial, or human (skills) capital.
The HO-SS theory, which dominated international economic thinking from the 1950s through 1970s, predicted that international trade would benefit the abundant factor of production (in rich countries, the owners of capital) and hurt the scarce factor of production (in rich countries, unskilled labor). Workers could command higher wages if they did not have to compete against abundant labor in poorer countries.
Then came the post-1980 revolutions in trade theory. Paul Krugman and Elhanan Helpman introduced the previously neglected elements of imperfect competition and increasing returns to scale. Later, in 2003, Marc Melitz showed how trade could shift resources from low-productivity to high-productivity firms.
Critics of globalization latched onto these newer economic theories, claiming that they demanded a rethinking of the traditional case for free trade. It was precisely at that time, however, that the HO-SS trade theory’s prediction that free trade would hurt lower-skill workers in rich countries apparently began to materialize.
Yet not all of the HO-SS theory’s predictions have come true. As Pinelopi Goldberg and Nina Pavcnik reported in 2007, the expectation that trade would reduce inequality in the countries with the most unskilled workers, because their services are in greater demand in an integrated world market, has not been borne out. “There is overwhelming evidence,” they write, “that less-skilled workers in developing countries “are generally not better off, at least not relative to workers with higher skill or education levels.” In the same year, Branko Milanović and Lyn Squire also found that tariff reduction is associated with higher inequality in poor countries.
Ten years later, inequality continues to worsen within developing countries, including the so-called BRICS emerging economies. In Brazil, the top 1% accounts for 25% of national income. In Russia, the income share of the top 1% of the population increased from 4% in 1980 to 20% in 2015. Likewise, in India, that figure rose from 6% in 1982 to 22% in 2013. In China, it surged from 6% in 1978 to 14% in 2015. And, in South Africa, it rose from 9% in 1987 to 19% in 2012. A look at the top 10% of earners shows similar trends.


This does not mean that the forces described by the HO-SS theory are irrelevant. But there is clearly more to current inequality trends than trade. Technological progress – which has raised demand for skilled workers relative to unskilled workers, at a time when the supply of skilled graduates lags – seems to be a major factor everywhere. The growing tendency of many professions to produce winner-take-all outcomes may play a role as well. A lack of redistribution through taxes in a country like the US (compared to major countries in Europe) does not help matters.
Inequality is clearly a serious problem that merits political attention. But focusing on trade is not the way to resolve it.


Jeffrey Frankel, a professor at Harvard University's Kennedy School of Government, previously served as a member of President Bill Clinton’s Council of Economic Advisers. He is a research associate at the US National Bureau of Economic Research, where he is a member of the Business Cycle Dating Committee, the official US arbiter of recession and recovery.

quarta-feira, 29 de janeiro de 2014

Capital in the 21st. century: a controversial book by Thomas Piketty

Cover: Capital in the Twenty-First Century, from Harvard University PressCover: Capital in the Twenty-First Century in HARDCOVER

Capital in the Twenty-First Century

Add to Cart

Book Details

HARDCOVER
$39.95 • £29.95 • €35.00
Publication: April 2014
Available 03/10/2014
696 pages
6-1/8 x 9-1/4 inches
96 graphs, 18 tables
World
What are the grand dynamics that drive the accumulation and distribution of capital? Questions about the long-term evolution of inequality, the concentration of wealth, and the prospects for economic growth lie at the heart of political economy. But satisfactory answers have been hard to find for lack of adequate data and clear guiding theories. In Capital in the Twenty-First CenturyThomas Piketty analyzes a unique collection of data from twenty countries, ranging as far back as the eighteenth century, to uncover key economic and social patterns. His findings will transform debate and set the agenda for the next generation of thought about wealth and inequality.
Piketty shows that modern economic growth and the diffusion of knowledge have allowed us to avoid inequalities on the apocalyptic scale predicted by Karl Marx. But we have not modified the deep structures of capital and inequality as much as we thought in the optimistic decades following World War II. The main driver of inequality—the tendency of returns on capital to exceed the rate of economic growth—today threatens to generate extreme inequalities that stir discontent and undermine democratic values. But economic trends are not acts of God. Political action has curbed dangerous inequalities in the past, Piketty says, and may do so again.
A work of extraordinary ambition, originality, and rigor, Capital in the Twenty-First Century reorients our understanding of economic history and confronts us with sobering lessons for today.

O capitalismo e a desigualdade: um debate nao isento de equivocosconceituais

Quando as pessoas argumentam que o capitalismo causa desigualdades, elas estão pretendendo uma contradição nos termos: um sistema de moto perpetuo, ou seja, a criação de riqueza sem as alavancas da criação de riquezas, uma impossibilidade prática.
Paulo Roberto de Almeida 

The Opinion Pages|CONTRIBUTING OP-ED WRITER

Capitalism vs. Democracy

Thomas B. Edsall
The New York Times, January 29, 2014
Thomas Piketty’s new book, “Capital in the Twenty-First Century,”described by one French newspaper as a “a political and theoretical bulldozer,” defies left and right orthodoxy by arguing that worsening inequality is an inevitable outcome of free market capitalism.
Piketty, a professor at the Paris School of Economics, does not stop there. He contends that capitalism’s inherent dynamic propels powerful forces that threaten democratic societies.
Capitalism, according to Piketty, confronts both modern and modernizing countries with a dilemma: entrepreneurs become increasingly dominant over those who own only their own labor. In Piketty’s view, while emerging economies can defeat this logic in the near term, in the long run, “when pay setters set their own pay, there’s no limit,” unless “confiscatory tax rates” are imposed.


Piketty’s book — published four months ago in France and due out in English this March — suggests that traditional liberal government policies on spending, taxation and regulation will fail to diminish inequality. Piketty has also delivered and posted a series of lectures in French and English outlining his argument.


Launch media viewer
Fig. 1: After-tax rate of return vs. growth rate at the world level from Antiquity until 2100. Thomas Piketty

Conservative readers will find that Piketty’s book disputes the view that the free market, liberated from the distorting effects of government intervention, “distributes,” as Milton Friedman famously put it, “the fruits of economic progress among all people. That’s the secret of the enormous improvements in the conditions of the working person over the past two centuries.”
Piketty proposes instead that the rise in inequality reflects markets working precisely as they should: “This has nothing to do with a market imperfection: the more perfect the capital market, the higher” the rate of return on capital is in comparison to the rate of growth of the economy. The higher this ratio is, the greater inequality is.
In a 20-page review for the June issue of the Journal of Economic Literature that has already caused a stir, Branko Milanovic, an economist in the World Bank’s research department, declared:
“I am hesitant to call Thomas Piketty’s new book Capital in the 21st Century one of the best books in economics written in the past several decades. Not that I do not believe it is, but I am careful because of the inflation of positive book reviews and because contemporaries are often poor judges of what may ultimately prove to be influential. With these two caveats, let me state that we are in the presence of one of the watershed books in economic thinking.”
There are a number of key arguments in Piketty’s book. One is that the six-decade period of growing equality in western nations – starting roughly with the onset of World War I and extending into the early 1970s – was unique and highly unlikely to be repeated. That period, Piketty suggests, represented an exception to the more deeply rooted pattern of growing inequality.
According to Piketty, those halcyon six decades were the result of two world wars and the Great Depression. The owners of capital – those at the top of the pyramid of wealth and income – absorbed a series of devastating blows. These included the loss of credibility and authority as markets crashed; physical destruction of capital throughout Europe in both World War I and World War II; the raising of tax rates, especially on high incomes, to finance the wars; high rates of inflation that eroded the assets of creditors; the nationalization of major industries in both England and France; and the appropriation of industries and property in post-colonial countries.
At the same time, the Great Depression produced the New Deal coalition in the United States, which empowered an insurgent labor movement. The postwar period saw huge gains in growth and productivity, the benefits of which were shared with workers who had strong backing from the trade union movement and from the dominant Democratic Party. Widespread support for liberal social and economic policy was so strong that even a Republican president who won easily twice, Dwight D. Eisenhower, recognized that an assault on the New Deal would be futile. In Eisenhower’s words, “Should any political party attempt to abolish Social Security, unemployment insurance, and eliminate labor laws and farm programs, you would not hear from that party again in our political history.”
The six decades between 1914 and 1973 stand out from the past and future, according to Piketty, because the rate of economic growth exceeded the after-tax rate of return on capital. Since then, the rate of growth of the economy has declined, while the return on capital is rising to its pre-World War I levels.
“If the rate of return on capital remains permanently above the rate of growth of the economy – this is Piketty’s key inequality relationship,” Milanovic writes in his review, this “generates a changing functional distribution of income in favor of capital and, if capital incomes are more concentrated than incomes from labor (a rather uncontroversial fact), personal income distribution will also get more unequal—which indeed is what we have witnessed in the past 30 years.”
Piketty has produced the chart at Figure 1 to illustrate his larger point.
The only way to halt this process, he argues, is to impose a global progressive tax on wealth – global in order to prevent (among other things) the transfer of assets to countries without such levies. A global tax, in this scheme, would restrict the concentration of wealth and limit the income flowing to capital.
Piketty would impose an annual graduated tax on stocks and bonds, property and other assets that are customarily not taxed until they are sold. He leaves open the rate and formula for distributing revenues.
The Piketty diagnosis helps explain the recent drop in the share of national income going to labor (see Figure 2) and a parallel increase in the share going to capital.
Piketty’s analysis also sheds light on the worldwide growth in the number of the unemployed. The International Labor Organization, an agency of the United Nations, reported recently that the number of unemployed grew by 5 million from 2012 to 2013, reaching nearly 202 million by the end of last year. It is projected to grow to 215 million by 2018.
Piketty’s wealth tax solution runs directly counter to the principles of contemporary American conservatives who advocate antithetical public policies: cutting top rates and eliminating the estate tax. It would also run counter to the interests of those countries that have purposefully legislated low tax rates in order to attract investment. The very infeasibility of establishing a global wealth tax serves to reinforce Piketty’s argument concerning the inevitability of increasing inequality.
Some Liberals are none too happy with Piketty, either.


Launch media viewer
Fig. 2: Nonfarm Business Sector: Labor Share U.S. Department of Labor

Dean Baker, one of the founders of the Center for Economic and Policy Research, wrote me in an email that he believes that Piketty “is far too pessimistic.” Baker contends that there are a host of far less ambitious actions that might help to ameliorate inequality:
“Is it really implausible that we would ever see any sort of tax on finance in the U.S., either the financial transactions tax that I would favor or the financial activities tax advocated by the I.M.F.?”
Baker also noted that “much of our capital is tied up in intellectual property” and that reform of patent laws could serve both to limit the value of drug and other patents and simultaneously lower consumer costs.
Lawrence Mishel, the president of the Economic Policy Institute, responded to my email asking for his take on Piketty:
“We’d take the perspective that this phenomenon is related to the suppression of wage growth so that policies which generate broad-based wage growth are an antidote. The political economy is such that the political power to enact those taxes also requires a mobilized citizenry and institutional power, such as a robust labor movement.”
Daron Acemoglu, a more centrist economist at MIT, praised Piketty’s careful acquisition of data, as well as his emphasis on the economic forces and political conflicts over distribution that shape inequality. In an email, Acemoglu went on to say:
“Part of his interpretation I do not share. Piketty argues that there is a natural tendency for high inequality in ‘capitalist’ economies (the term capitalist is not my favorite) and that certain unusual events (world wars, the Great Depression and policy responses thereto) temporarily reduced inequality. Then both earnings inequality and inequality between capital and labor have been reverting back to their ‘normal’ levels. I don’t think that the data allow us to reach this conclusion. All we see is this pattern of fall and rise, but so many other things are going on. It is consistent with what Piketty says, but it is also consistent with certain technological changes and discontinuities (or globalization) having created a surge in inequality which will then stabilize or even reverse in the next several decades. It is also consistent with the dynamics of political power changing and this being a major contributor to the rise in inequality in advanced economies. We may be seeing parts of several different trends underpinned by several different major shocks rather than the mean-reverting dynamics following the shocks that Piketty singles out.”
There is, however, significant liberal applause for Piketty.
Richard Freeman, an economist at Harvard who specializes in inequality, unions and employment patterns, wrote me by email:
“I am in 100 percent agreement with Piketty and would add that much of labor inequality comes because high earners got paid through stock options and capital ownership.”>
Freeman and two colleagues, Joseph Blasi and Douglas Kruse, professors at the School of Labor and Management Relations at Rutgers, contend in their 2013 book, “The Citizen’s Share: Putting Ownership Back into Democracy,” that they have an alternative to a global wealth tax. They argue that:
“The way forward is to reform the structure of American business so that workers can supplement their wages with significant capital ownership stakes and meaningful capital income and profit shares.”
In other words, let’s turn everyone into a capitalist.
Piketty does not treat worker ownership as a solution, and he is generally dismissive of small-bore reforms, arguing that they will have only modest effects on economic growth worldwide, which he believes is very likely to be stuck at 1 to 1.5 percent through the rest of this century.
Piketty’s joins a number of scholars raising significant questions about how the global economic system will deal with such phenomena asrobotics, the hollowing out of the job market, outsourcing and global competition.
His prognosis is extremely bleak. Without what he acknowledges is a politically unrealistic global wealth tax, he sees the United States and the developed world on a path toward a degree of inequality that will reach levels likely to cause severe social disruption.
Final judgment on Piketty’s work will come with time – a problem in and of itself, because if he is right, inequality will worsen, making it all the more difficult to take preemptive action.

segunda-feira, 22 de novembro de 2010

Brasil: consequencias politicas da reducao da desigualdade - Oxford University

Um importante encontro para debate entre especialistas, numa área em que crenças políticas, simpatias partidárias e honestidade científica se juntam para complicar justamente a dimensão política desse fenômeno real no Brasil.
Suas consequências políticas são mais difíceis de serem avaliadas, pois elas penetram no subconsciente nacional, ou melhor, na psicologia das massas, como se diria antigamente.

Workshop:  “Political Consequences of Declining Inequality in Brazil”
University of Oxford, 3 December
****************************
co-sponsored by the Brazilian Studies Programme (www.brazil.ox.ac.uk) and the Oxford Centre for the Study of Inequality and Democracy (ocsid.politics.ox.ac.uk)

Friday, 3 December 2010
Tawney Room, Rewley House, 1 Wellington Square with the generous support of Santander Universities (www.santander.com)

Although Brazil remains a world leader in inequality, the Gini coefficient of income inequality has been falling perceptibly since the early 1990s. The past 5-7 years have seen a notable reduction in poverty rates, with some analysts heralding the emergence of a “new middle class.” Factors contributing to this trend include renewed economic growth, improved education, sustained increases in the minimum wage, and innovative social policies introduced by the past two governments. In particular, the conditional cash transfer programme known as Bolsa Família has generated intense interest both in Brazil and abroad. While economists, sociologists, and demographers have been swift to document the decline in poverty and inequality in Brazil, few have explored the political implications of these trends.
Given that the institutions and practices of Brazilian politics have long been causally linked to the presence of deep inequalities in the country, this day-long workshop aims to analyse both the macropolitical and micropolitical consequences of recent social changes. The key questions are whether (1) government social policy and (2) the declining economic vulnerability of the poor make any difference for the politics of democracy in Brazil.
The workshop will feature nine papers from social scientists who will appraise the implications of social change for democratic development. Topics include electoral realignments, the possible
erosion of oligarchy, new approaches to clientelism and “exchange politics,” political implications of rising labor formality and improved educational/literacy outputs, the impact on governance of rising living standards in peripheral communities, the effects of improving social indicators on longstanding ideological divisions between left and right, the possible accrual of a long-term political legacy for Lula’s PT, and the extent to which subnational politicians (governors and mayors) engage in credit-
claiming. The majority of papers focus centrally on Bolsa Família, allowing us to advance the emerging theoretical debates on the implications of conditional cash transfers for democracy
and development. We will conclude the day with a keynote presentation by Dr Marcelo Neri of the Centre for Social Policies, Getúlio Vargas Foundation, who will lay out the empirical panorama of the recent reduction in Brazilian inequality.

9:05-10:45    Panel 1: Patterns of Voting and Public Opinion
Chair: Andrew Hurrell (University of Oxford)
“Realignment in Brazil”
André Singer (University of São Paulo)
“Poorest Voters vs. Poorest Places: Persistent Patterns and Recent Changes in Brazilian Electoral Patterns”
Cesar Zucco Jr. (Princeton University)
“Electoral Gains and Losses from Conditional Cash Transfer Programs: How Bolsa Família Led to the Polarization of the Brazilian Electorate”
Diego Sanches Correa (University of Illinois)
Discussant: Anthony W. Pereira (King’s College, London)

11:00-12:30   Panel 2: New Perspectives on Clientelism and Exchange Politics
Chair: Nancy Bermeo (University of Oxford)
“Creating Citizens or Clients: The Impact of Bolsa Família in Brazil”
Wendy Hunter (University of Texas at Austin)
“Their Separate Ways: Leftist Mobilization and Clientelist Continuity in Brazilian Subnational Politics”
Alfred P. Montero (Carleton College)
“Agents of Citizenship or Agents of Clientelism? The Cultural Dilemma of Bolsa Família’s State Monitors.”
Presented by Luciana Veiga (Universidade Federal do Paraná) on behalf of co-authors Simone Bohn (York University), Salete da Dalt (Universidade Federal Fluminense), André Augusto Pereira Brandão (Universidade Federal Fluminense), César Augusto da Silva (Federal University of Vale do São Francisco), and Victor Hugo de Carvalho Gouvêa (Universidade Federal Fluminense)
Discussant: David Doyle (Dublin City University)

14:00-15:30   Panel 3: Framing the Public Debate on Redistribution
Chair: Alessandra Aldé (Universidade do Estado do Rio de Janeiro)
“Inequality and Support for Redistribution”
Fabiana Machado (Inter-American Development Bank)
“The Debate on the Reduction of Inequality in Brazil: An Analysis of the 2010 Presidential Campaign”
Marcia Ribeiro Dias (Pontifícia Universidade Católica, Rio Grande do Sul)
“Coalitions for Equity-Enhancing Reform in Brazil”
Diego Sánchez-Ancochea and Timothy J. Power (University of Oxford)
Discussant: Camille Goirand (University of Lille)

15:45-17:30   Panel 4: Keynote Address
Chair: Antonio David Cattani (Universidade Federal do Rio Grande do Sul)
“The Decade of Inequality Reduction in Brazil: Causes, Consequences and Perspectives”
Marcelo Neri (Fundação Getúlio Vargas, Rio de Janeiro)
Discussant: Edmund Amann (University of Manchester)

17:30-18:00   Closing Remarks and Adjournment

FOR MORE INFO and to register, please contact: david.robinson@lac.ox.ac.uk prior to 30 November 2010