O que é este blog?

Este blog trata basicamente de ideias, se possível inteligentes, para pessoas inteligentes. Ele também se ocupa de ideias aplicadas à política, em especial à política econômica. Ele constitui uma tentativa de manter um pensamento crítico e independente sobre livros, sobre questões culturais em geral, focando numa discussão bem informada sobre temas de relações internacionais e de política externa do Brasil. Para meus livros e ensaios ver o website: www.pralmeida.org. Para a maior parte de meus textos, ver minha página na plataforma Academia.edu, link: https://itamaraty.academia.edu/PauloRobertodeAlmeida.

Mostrando postagens com marcador Geoeconomic Fragmentation. Mostrar todas as postagens
Mostrando postagens com marcador Geoeconomic Fragmentation. Mostrar todas as postagens

segunda-feira, 16 de janeiro de 2023

Geoeconomic Fragmentation and the Future of Multilateralism - Shekhar Aiyar et alii (IMF Staff Discussion Notes)

Geoeconomic Fragmentation and the Future of Multilateralism 

Prepared by Shekhar Aiyar, Jiaqian Chen, Christian Ebeke, Roberto Garcia-Saltos, Tryggvi Gudmundsson, Anna Ilyina, Alvar Kangur, Tansaya Kunaratskul, Sergio Rodriguez, Michele Ruta, Tatjana Schulze, Gabriel Soderberg, and Juan Pedro Trevinio

IMF Staff Discussion Notes, January 2023

Summary:

After several decades of increasing global economic integration, the world is facing the risk of policy-driven geoeconomic fragmentation (GEF). This note explores the ramifications. It identifies multiple channels through which the benefits of globalization were earlier transmitted, and along which, conversely, the costs of GEF are likely to fall, including trade, migration, capital flows, technology diffusion and the provision of global public goods. It explores the consequences of GEF for the international monetary system and the global financial safety net. Finally, it suggests a pragmatic path forward for preserving the benefits of global integration and multilateralism.


Do meu lado, concordo com a premissas da fragmentação, mas não creio que intelectuais, ou burocratas, tenham condições de reverter as tendências negativas do presente, processo que depende de estadistas dotados de enorme capacidade de persuasão recíproca, entre os líderes dos três impérios e meio, para encaminhar a política mundial para uma fase menos conflitiva.

Por três impérios e meio entendo serem EUA, China, Rússia (apenas no plano militar) e a UE, todo o resto sendo caudatário de quaisquer entendimentos possíveis entre esses grandes. (PRA)


Executive Summary 

After decades of increasing global economic integration, the world is facing the risk of fragmentation. A shallow and uneven recovery from the global financial crisis (GFC) was followed by Brexit, U.S.–-China trade tensions, and a growing number of military conflicts. The post-GFC era has seen a leveling-off of global flows of goods and capital, and a surge in trade restrictions. The COVID-19 pandemic and Russia’s invasion of Ukraine have further tested international relations and increased skepticism about the benefits of globalization. This Staff Discussion Note explores the potential economic ramifications of a policy-driven reversal of global economic integration, a multidimensional process that the authors refer to as geoeconomic fragmentation (GEF). 

The benefits of globalization propagate through multiple channels; the adverse consequences of GEF would be felt in many areas as well. For several decades, trade deepening has helped catalyze catch-up in per capita incomes across countries and a large reduction in global poverty, while in advanced economies, low-income consumers have benefited disproportionately through lower prices. Conversely, the unraveling of trade links would most adversely impact low-income countries and less well-off consumers in advanced economies. Restrictions on cross-border migration would deprive host economies of valuable skills while reducing remittances in migrant-sending economies. Reduced capital flows would hinder financial deepening in destination countries, especially through foreign direct investment which can be an important source of technological diffusion. And a decline in international cooperation would put at risk the provision of vital global public goods. 

Estimates of the costs of GEF from economic modeling vary widely. Available studies suggest that the deeper the fragmentation, the deeper the costs; that technological decoupling significantly amplifies losses from trade restrictions; that adjustment costs are likely to be large; and that emerging market economies and low-income countries are likely to be most at risk due to the loss of knowledge spillovers. Depending on modeling assumptions, the cost to global output from trade fragmentation could range from 0.2 percent (in a limited fragmentation / low-cost adjustment scenario) to up to 7 percent of GDP (in a severe fragmentation / high-cost adjustment scenario); with the addition of technological decoupling, the loss in output could reach 8 to 12 percent in some countries. More work is needed to assess and aggregate the costs through multiple channels. 

GEF could strain the international monetary system and the global financial safety net (GFSN). Financial globalization could give way to “financial regionalization” and a fragmented global payment system. With less international risk-sharing, GEF could lead to higher macroeconomic volatility, more severe crises, and greater pressures on national buffers. Facing fragmentation risks, countries may look to diversify away from traditional reserve assets —a process that could be accelerated by digitalization— potentially leading to higher financial volatility, at least during transition. By hampering international cooperation, GEF could also weaken the capacity of the GFSN to support crisis countries and complicate the resolution of future sovereign debt crises. 

To avert runaway fragmentation, the rules-based multilateral system must adapt to the changing world. This includes the international trade and monetary systems. Given current geopolitical realities, progress through multilateral consensus may not always be possible. Trust may have to be rebuilt gradually through differential engagements depending on the countries’ preferences and willingness to work together. Where preferences are broadly aligned, multilateral cooperation remains the best approach to address global challenges. In areas like climate change and pandemics such cooperation is essential. When multilateral efforts stall, open and nondiscriminatory plurilateral initiatives (fewer countries wanting to do more) could be a practical way forward. When countries opt for unilateral actions, credible “guardrails” may be needed to mitigate global spillovers and protect the vulnerable (such as “safe corridors” for food and medicine). Addressing these challenges requires a joint effort of all international organizations, including the IMF. To be effective in a more shock-prone world, the IMF should remain representative of its global membership and at the core of the reinforced GFSN.