O que é este blog?

Este blog trata basicamente de ideias, se possível inteligentes, para pessoas inteligentes. Ele também se ocupa de ideias aplicadas à política, em especial à política econômica. Ele constitui uma tentativa de manter um pensamento crítico e independente sobre livros, sobre questões culturais em geral, focando numa discussão bem informada sobre temas de relações internacionais e de política externa do Brasil. Para meus livros e ensaios ver o website: www.pralmeida.org. Para a maior parte de meus textos, ver minha página na plataforma Academia.edu, link: https://itamaraty.academia.edu/PauloRobertodeAlmeida;

Meu Twitter: https://twitter.com/PauloAlmeida53

Facebook: https://www.facebook.com/paulobooks

Mostrando postagens com marcador Dicionarios de economia. Mostrar todas as postagens
Mostrando postagens com marcador Dicionarios de economia. Mostrar todas as postagens

terça-feira, 10 de maio de 2011

Um Dicionario brasileiro de Economia: bem-vindo, mas pode melhorar - Paulo Roberto de Almeida

Minha colaboração à base de dados dos dicionários de economia limitou-se a informar sobre uma nova edição, ampliada, de um conhecido dicionário publicado no Brasil, este aqui:

A economia, em centímetros quadrados...
Brasília, 16 junho 2006, 4 p.
Resenha de Paulo Sandroni:
Dicionário de Economia do século XXI
(Rio de Janeiro: Record, 2005, 905 p.; ISBN: 85-01-07228-1).
Publicado na Desafios do Desenvolvimento (Brasília: IPEA-PNUD. Ano 3, nº 24, julho 2006, p. 54-55; link: http://desafios2.ipea.gov.br/desafios/edicoes/24/artigo22752-1.php e http://desafios2.ipea.gov.br/desafios/edicoes/24/artigo22752-2.php).
Revisto e ampliado e publicado sob o título “A economia, explicada aos jornalistas (e outros curiosos)” no Observatório da Imprensa (Ano 11, nº 388, de 4/07/2006; ISSN: 1519-7670; link: http://observatorio.ultimosegundo.ig.com.br/artigos.asp?cod=388AZL002).
Relação de Publicados n. 672.

Como provavelmente os links existentes à época já não estão mais funcionando, transcrevo aqui esta minha resenha:

A economia, em centímetros quadrados...

Paulo Sandroni:
Dicionário de Economia do século XXI
(Rio de Janeiro: Record, 2005, 905 p.; ISBN: 85-01-07228-1)

Nos dicionários – como nas enciclopédias –, espaço é tudo. A “centimetragem” dos verbetes costuma refletir a importância relativa de cada um. Por isso, pode parecer bizarro que, neste dicionário, o espaço ocupado pelo “mágico de Oz” (yes, o famoso personagem de Frank Baum) represente duas vezes o alocado ao verbete “capitalismo”: duas páginas inteiras (de duas colunas) para o “mágico”, contra, apenas, 3/4 de uma única página para o capitalismo, sendo que seu ex-inimigo, o defunto “comunismo”, ganha uma página e meia. Esta é uma das peculiaridades desta, ainda assim, utilíssima ferramenta de consulta que não deixa de refletir os gostos e preferências de seu autor, um bem sucedido professor de economia, hoje convertido em sinônimo de obra de referência.
Sim, a partir da quinta edição de uma obra publicada originalmente em 1985, para acompanhar a coleção “Os Economistas” (da Abril), já se pode falar do “Sandroni”, como hoje usualmente se fala do “Aurélio”, com algumas diferenças, no entanto. Se o “primo” da língua portuguesa procura seguir o cânon da Academia Brasileira de Letras, Sandroni não segue nenhum padrão consagrado, a não ser o seu próprio. Será por isso que o verbete “protecionismo” ostenta o dobro do espaço dado ao “livre-comércio”? Não parece estranho, novamente, que o Mercosul ocupe menos da metade do espaço atribuído ao Nafta, ao passo que um acordo que ainda nem existe, a Alca, tem mais do dobro deste último? Infelizmente, o verbete Mercosul não é apenas insuficiente, mas claramente inadequado, inclusive conceitualmente. Se o Mercosul dependesse do “Sandroni” para validar sua relevância, já estaria condenado ao museu das antiguidades, ao lado do machado de bronze e da roca de fiar, como previa Engels para o destino do Estado.
Esse tipo de inconsistência não passaria por uma academia de economia, se esta servisse para dar chancela a dicionários do gênero. Não que Sandroni tenha trabalhado inteiramente sozinho: os créditos consignam pelo menos três dúzias de consultores, mais três dezenas de pesquisadores. Mas ele certamente exerceu o direito de ir aumentando, aqui e ali, as fichas individuais, cada vez que um tema crescia em importância em sua mente. Daí o caráter irregular de algumas informações, bem como erros primários de revisão (o verbete “monocultura”, por exemplo, é repetido na imediata sequência). Não se trata apenas de espaço desigual, mas, também, de insuficiências notórias ou deslizes clamorosos. Assim como certos verbetes – “Escola Clássica”, por exemplo – apresentam quase uma aula sobre o assunto, outros induzem a erro: Hayek nunca foi “neoliberal”, pela simples razão que ele sempre foi um liberal clássico, tout court.
Mas, por que a “interpretação econômica” do “mágico de Oz” valeria duas vezes e meia a descrição do capitalismo? Sem cair novamente nas preferências do autor, digamos que a fábula de Baum ilustre os dilemas da transição do bimetalismo (ouro e prata) ao monometalismo do padrão-ouro na construção dos sistemas monetários nacionais, durante a segunda onda da globalização (final do século XIX e início do seguinte). Ainda assim, há um notório exagero na dimensão do verbete (que, aliás, está bem escrito).
A atualização de alguns verbetes também deixa a desejar, considerando-se a data do “fechamento”: julho de 2005. Mesmo dando-se desconto de um ano, é inexplicável que o verbete consagrado ao Mercado Comum Europeu diga que a entidade “congrega” (assim, no presente) doze membros, quando o MCE já se tinha diluído na Comunidade Econômica Européia desde 1967, sendo esta substituída pela expressão Comunidades Européias na década seguinte. A União Européia, por sua vez, existe desde 1993, tendo passado de doze a quinze membros dois anos mais tarde; ela admitiu dez membros adicionais em 2004, levando-a aos 25 membros atuais (encore plus em negociações). Mais surpreendente ainda, MCE remete ao verbete “União Européia”, que simplesmente não existe, esquecido entre a União Escandinava (uma união monetária que funcionou entre 1873 e 1905) e a União Européia de Pagamentos (um sistema de pagamentos compensados que deixou de existir em 1958). Surpreendente ou inexplicável, esse tipo de omissão é imperdoável num dicionário do “século XXI”.
Na verdade, pouca coisa pertence ao século XXI, a maior parte vinda dos séculos XIX e XX, mas o verbete FMI já traz Rodrigo Rato como seu diretor, a partir de 2004. Os temas recentes estão registrados, como o “indice Big Mac” da The Economist, o “consenso de Washington” (erroneamente definido como sendo uma defesa do “Estado mínimo”) e os acordos de Basiléia 1 e 2 (normas prudenciais para atividades bancárias). Mas, para um dicionário do século XXI, o verbete “globalização” não poderia ser mais anêmico: escassas dez linhas (em meia coluna, recorde-se), ainda assim voltado mais para o fenômeno do “global sourcing” do que para os processos de integração de mercados. Talvez o autor não goste da globalização, mas ela ainda assim existe e incomoda.
Interessantes e úteis são os verbetes dedicados às idiossincrasias econômicas brasileiras, como o jogo do bicho – cálculos de probabilidade indicam que os banqueiros ficam com 60 a 70% das receitas –, as mordomias, tais como oficialmente definidas pela administração, ou os diversos planos brasileiros de desenvolvimento e de estabilização econômica. Comparecem sínteses históricas sobre a legislação e os padrões monetários, sobre os valores do salário mínimo, bem como listas de ministérios e de ministros da Fazenda do Brasil: Itamar foi um campeão de ministros!
Alguns erros precisam ser corrigidos numa futura edição. Assim, o Gatt não foi substituído pela OMC, em 1995, mas sim incorporado à rede de acordos administrados por ela; ele tampouco tem por princípio básico o livre-comércio, apenas visa à mais ampla liberalização comercial possível. O economista André Gunder Frank, identificado com o “desenvolvimento do subdesenvolvimento”, aparece duas vezes, nas letras F e G, sendo que Gunder é mais “desenvolvido” do que Frank. Os GAB são mais comumente referidos como General Arrangements to Borrow, e não como Agreements, uma vez que eles não derivam de tratados formais e sim de esquemas especiais. Dizer que Hobbes era um “mercantilista” e acrescentar, em seguida, que ele considerava a liberdade de comércio uma “lei natural” parece uma contradição nos termos.
Keynes não foi o primeiro “presidente” do FMI, mas sim o representante britânico (governor) na primeira assembléia-geral das duas organizações de Bretton Woods (em Savannah, na Georgia, em 1946), ocasião na qual ele indicou o belga Camille Gutt como o primeiro “diretor-gerente” do FMI. Bilateralismo e multilateralismo estão definidos de forma restrita, vinculados apenas ao comércio. Da mesma forma, reciprocidade em comércio não quer dizer fair trade e sim concessões equivalentes, não necessariamente simétricas. Em regimes cambiais, o abandono do acordo de Bretton Woods pelos EUA se deu, de fato, em 1971, mas o fim da jurisdição do FMI sobre esses regimes só foi alcançado em 1973. Esses pequenos erros não empanam o valor de uma obra grandiosa.
No terreno do humor econômico, ele incorpora um verbete para a conhecida lei de Murphy, mas se esquece da lei de Parkinson, altamente relevante para a “produtividade” na administração pública: o total de empregados numa burocracia cresce 5 a 7% ao ano, independentemente de qualquer variação no volume de trabalho que deve ser feito. Parafraseando, digamos que o tamanho de um dicionário como este aumenta entre 20 e 30% a cada edição, independentemente da importância relativa dos verbetes. Mas, pela “lei de Gresham” dos dicionários, volumes menores e de menor qualidade começarão a fazer concorrência implacável ao “Sandroni”.
Ele deve sustentar a competição, mas caberia pensar, numa próxima edição, em adaptá-lo aos tempos modernos: não é possível que um dicionário que se pretenda do “século XXI” dedique mais de uma página à “revolução socialista” e escassas 14 linhas (de meia coluna) aos verbetes “pobreza” e “riqueza”, que constituem o próprio âmago da ciência econômica. Mesmo numa concepção tradicional, alguns desequilíbrios devem ser corrigidos: hoje, Raúl Prebisch vence Adam Smith por meia coluna; o socialismo deixa longe o capitalismo e a definição deste último é basicamente marxista; que Stalin receba a mesma “centimetragem” de Keynes indica uma desproporção inaceitável numa obra de economia. Estou de acordo em que a “teoria da dependência” não mereça mesmo mais de 13 linhas, mas que “trabalho alienado” supere em quatro vezes “vantagens comparativas” revela uma inclinação hoje démodée. Proponho uma revisão “bibliométrica” nos 6 mil verbetes do Dicionário, tendo como critério o velho preceito marxista (aliás emprestado do economista William Goodwin): a cada um segundo as suas necessidades...

Paulo Roberto de Almeida
[Brasília, 1618: 16 junho 2006]

Dicionarios de economia: uma base de dados internacional - Daniele Besomi

Uma base de dados relativamente completa sobre todos os dicionários de economia compilados ao longo dos tês últimos séculos.

As one of the outcomes of a recent research, I have compiled a list of dictionaries of economics and related disciplines (about 650 titles for more than 1,100 different editions, from Choel's 1709 to today). I have posted it here:
http://www.danielebesomi.ch/dictionaries/bibliography.
As the above-mentioned work I undertook with some colleagues involved entries on crises and cycles and related subjects, a number of these (the copyright free ones) are also posted on the web site, at
http://www.danielebesomi.ch/dictionaries/crises_in_dictionaries/entries_crises/crises_entries.html.
This includes entries authored by writers such as Blanqui, Juglar, Tugan-Baranowsky, Edgeworth Mitchell, Spiethoff and others.

I hope this list of dictionaries and its sorting according to different criteria (chronological, by compiler, by size, language and scope) may be of some use: after all, dictionaries are not only reference sources for contemporaries, but taken as a whole they are precious witnesses for posterity concerning the moods, views, approaches, theories and styles of their epoch.

Although I have tried to produce a list as exhaustive as possible, I may have missed some items in the main European languages, and I have surely missed most in the languages of which I have no understanding. I would appreciate if you could communicate any relevant omission you may notice by means of this form:
http://www.danielebesomi.ch/dictionaries/submission_form/dictionaries_submission_form.php;
please only focus on monolingual dictionaries and ignore handbooks, textbooks etc. Thank you very much.

Best, Daniele Besomi

Um exemplo: Um Dicionário das Crises Econômicas:

Crises and cycles in dictionaries and encyclopedias

Abstracts
1. INTRODUCTION (DANIELE BESOMI)
This introductory chapter explains the rationale of dedicating an entire volume to the study of a specific subject—crises and cycles— as discussed in dictionaries and encyclopedia. The first lies in the nature of writings prepared for such reference works, a truly scientific-literary genre with its own specific features, in particular self-containedness, (relative) briefness, monographical and often educational character, and expert authorship, which make these entries of particular interest for historians of thought. Not only individual dictionary entries, some of which written by writers of absolute eminence, are informative on the subject and the views on the subject held at the time of writing, but taken as a whole such corpus of writings reflects the development of the understanding of the subject through almost two centuries of history of economic doctrines.

2. A BRIEF HISTORY OF ECONOMIC DICTIONARIES. AN ESSAY IN BIBLIOGRAPHY (DANIELE BESOMI)
This chapter outlines a history of specialized dictionaries in economics and allied disciplines, presenting them grouped by their scope in chronological order. The first dictionaries qualifying themselves as ‘economic’ were in reality concerned with practical arts and agriculture (18th and early 19th century). There followed a number of commercial and financial dictionaries in the 18th century and throughout the 19th century. The former eventually turned, early in the 20th century, into general business dictionaries, while financial dictionaries are still published nowadays. The first dictionary dedicated to political economy was published in 1826, it was followed by a dozen extensive works in the remainder of the century and a myriad of smaller sized works in the 20th century. Meanwhile more general dictionaries dedicated to social sciences also began to be published. In the late 20th century, a number of sectorial and biographical dictionaries also appeared. The chapter finally offers a quantitative survey of the distribution of dictionaries according to scope, size and language.

3. NAMING CRISES. A NOTE ON SEMANTICS AND CHRONOLOGY (DANIELE BESOMI)
This essay examines the main terms used to indicate crises, cycles and related phenomena since the early 18th century. Of each term are examined the etymology, the definitions and the (sometimes drastic) evolution of their usage in time, both in the general literature and in economic dictionaries. The terms are: Glut, Distress, Embarrassment, Stagnation, Panic, Bubble, Depression, Fluctuations, Recession, Crisis and Cycle. The latter two are those most widely used, and are thus discussed in more detail.

4. DICTIONARY RECONSTRUCTIONS OF THE HISTORY OF THE THEORIES OF CRISES AND CYCLES. A META-TAXONOMY (DANIELE BESOMI)
This chapter surveys the classificatory approaches of business cycles and crises theories found in dictionary articles. These are found to belong to a surprisingly small number of types. At first, dictionary writers only cited the theories they wanted to disprove. Then (especially in Germany in the second half of the 19th century), writers were classified according to their acceptance, or rejection, of Say’s law, or depending on their political views. When cycles theories had completely displaced the previous emphasis on crises, the dividing line run through the ‘old’ or ‘new’ approaches (interwar years). Up to the 1950s, emphasis moved onto the classification of the causes of cycles, and a bit later on the formal properties of models. Finally, a more fundamental line of division was sought, considering theories in the context of different economic schools, or again with respect to the acceptance of Say’s law, or on the emphasis on endogenous or exogenous causes, or on the stability of equilibrium.

5. BETWEEN PROGRESS AND DECLINE: CRISES IN EARLY FRENCH DICTIONARIES AND ENCYCLOPEDIAS (1830–1840) (LUDOVIC FROBERT)
This chapter deals with the very first entries on ‘Crisis’ or ‘Crises’ in French encyclopaedias and dictionaries of the 1830s. It is during these years that the first dramatic and regular economic crises arose in the French economy. At the time, the analyses of this phenomenon were strictly associated with a wider reflection on the progress of the new industrial societies. That is why one could not hope to understand the early analyses of crisis without refering to the theme of Progress. In this chapter are presented four different visions of the relationship between crisis and Progress, as they were introduced by the main economic sects of the times: the Liberals, the Republicans, the Saint-Simonians, and the Fourierists.

6. THE ANALYSIS OF CRISES IN EARLY FRENCH DICTIONARIES AND ENCYCLOPEDIAS (DANIELE BESOMI)
This chapter examines the features of the 6 earliest articles on commercial crises published in economic dictionaries and in encyclopedias, 1835–42. It is noted that they offered the very first definitions of ‘crises’ found in the literature, although the conception was still rather trivial, as most of them saw crises as a disruption of the course of business. They admitted, however, endogenous as well as exogenous causes, but only some of them recognized some systematic character in their occurrence, and only one of these writers (Lemonnier) understood that they are a necessary consequence of technological advances and are therefore the price to pay for economic progress.

7. WILHELM ROSCHER’S CRISES THEORY: FROM PRODUCTION CRISES TO SALES CRISES (HARALD HAGEMANN)
In his early essay on production crises, which he later replaced by the term sales crises to characterize the essence of the disease, namely a lack of effective demand, Roscher made a very important argument. The consequence of the role of money as a store of value is the separation of the act of purchase and the act of sale. Although it had been the young John Stuart Mill, who first made this argument which is in the centre of all later critique of Say’s law, as for example in Marx and Keynes, Roscher put much more emphasis on that characteristic element of a monetary economy than the later Mill in his Principles. This makes Roscher’s essay a lasting contribution in the history of crises theories.

8. CHARLES COQUELIN: BANKING MONOPOLY AND COMMERCIAL CRISES (DANIELE BESOMI)
This chapter examines Charles Coquelin’s contribution to the theory of crises in his own and Guillemin’s Dictionnaire de l’économie politique (1852). The constantly operating cause he identified lies in the monopoly of the bank of issue. This causes a cumulation of tension within the system, as commercial banks deposit with the central bank the capitals they find difficult to place at remunerative rates thereby permitting the bank of issue to continuously expand its discounts, until the situation becomes too fragile to be sustained. Coquelin’s contribution is appreciated especially in terms of his epistemic reflections on the necessity of singling out a common cause that explains all the crises, laying the foundations for formulating a general law of crises.

9. COMMERCIAL CRISIS AND CREDIT IN THE FIRST SPANISH GENERAL ENCYCLOPAEDIA (1851–1855) (JESUS ASTIGARRAGA & JUAN ZABALZA)
The entries ‘Crédito’ and ‘Crisis comercial’ in the Enciclopedia moderna, the first Spanish general encyclopaedia, were drafted by J. J. Mora in the early 1850s. A large part of both entries was taken from a French mid-19th century commercial dictionary. Apart from the obvious aim of providing with information about the phenomena of commercial crisis and credit, Mora, who was a committed defender of free-trade, intended to place the analysis of commercial crisis and credit within the context of the debate on economic freedom and free trade that took place in Spain in the mid–19th century.

10. EXPECTATIONS AND CRISES IN AUGUSTE OTT’S DICTIONNAIRE DES SCIENCES POLITIQUES ET SOCIALES (1854) (DANIELE BESOMI)
In his Dictionnaire des sciences politiques et sociales (1854), Auguste Ott (an otherwise obscure systematizer of Philippe Buchez’s theory of social economic) contributed one of the few French criticisms of Say’s law, and formulated a theory of crises based on the systematic disappointment of expectations. These are formed on the grounds of limited information as to the the state of demand and supply, and are driven by the movement of prices. High prices are taken by entrepreneurs to indicate thriving demand, which indices them to increase production without realizing that other entrepreneurs are doing the same, thus causing an excess of production. Such emphasis on expectations was sixty years ahead of the modern treatment of this subject by the Swedes in the interwar years.

11. GEROLAMO BOCCARDO ON INTERNALLY GENERATED COMMERCIAL CRISES (1857) (DANIELE BESOMI)
Although Gerolamo Boccardo did not contribute an original theory of crises in his own Dizionario della economia politica (1857)—he relied, in fact, on the one formulated a few years earlied by Charles Coquelin— he introduced some interesting innovations. In particular, he examined the relationships between different kinds of crises (commercial, agricultural and industrial), and discussed the exogenous and endogenous character of crises not only in terms of their causes, but in terms of the possibility of theorizing them.

12. CLÉMENT JUGLAR 1863/1891: TRACKING AND INTERPRETING THE PERIODIC RETURN OF CRISES (CÉCILE DANGEL-HAGNAUER)
Although the ‘Juglar cycle’ is familiar to many people, even in the general public, Juglar’s actual contribution to the emergence of the theory of business cycles has been, to a large extent, ignored. His conception must indeed be dug out from the jumble of statistics and historical considerations contained in the two editions of his major work, Des crises commerciales et de leur retour périodique en France, en Angleterre et aux Etats-Unis. In contrast, the two entries examined here, published very shortly (in 1863 and 1891) after the publication of the two editions of the book (1862 and 1889), are concise and to the point. They also reflect the evolution of Juglar’s approach to the phenomenon of crises and their periodic return.

13. HENRY D. MACLEOD’S DICTIONARY OF POLITICAL ECONOMY: BRITAIN’S FIRST ABORTED ATTEMPT (CÉCILE DANGEL-HAGNAUER)
A controversial figure in the history of economics, Macleod is considered today as having made interesting contributions to the theory of money, credit, banking and finance. He is also the first Briton to have tried to publish a Dictionary of political economy. His attempt ended however in failure, as he never managed to go beyond the first volume, which contains nevertheless an entry on commercial crises. This entry provides an historical account of the crises that affected England in the century that preceded the publication of the Dictionary. It shows that Macleod had a good understanding of the role played by the central bank as lender of last resort, although the notion does not stand at the centre of his argument.

14. ADOLF WAGNER: ECONOMIC CRISES, CAPITALISM AND HUMAN NATURE (VITANTONIO GIOIA)
This chapter focuses on Wagner’s contribution to the theory of economic crises. In the entry Krisen of the Handwőrterbuch der Volkswirthschaftslehre (1866), Wagner rejects Roscher’s approach to this subject in order to reestablish the explicative meaning of Say’s law. According to Wagner, the causes of crises have to be looked for not in an alleged pathology or “structural defect” of the economic system, but in the consequences of human behaviour that turn the economic opportunities provided by the free-market into risky activities sustained by over-speculative attitudes.

15. EMILE DE LAVELEYE. ECONOMIC CRISES, CHRISTIANITY AND SOCIALISM (LUDOVIC FROBERT)
The aim of this chapter is to present Émile de Laveleye’s entry on commercial crisis published in La Grande Encyclopédie around 1890. Laveleye’s intuitions have to be analysed in the light of his whole intellectual project. It is particularly important to point out the link between his reflections on crises and, on the one hand, his Christian ethos, and on another hand, his involvement in Socialist movements. The chapter begins with a survey of Laveleye’s intellectual sources. Then his more general thesis is analysed, as presented in other essays, notably Primitive Property. Finally, their impact on his conception of commercial crisis is examined.

16. CRISES AND RELATED ENTRIES IN PALGRAVE’S DICTIONARY OF POLITICAL ECONOMY, 1894-99 (PASCAL BRIDEL)
This chapter examines the four entries devoted to crisis, periodicity of crises, commercial and financial crises and over production published between 1894 and 1899 in the three-volume ‘old’ Palgrave Dictionary of Political Economy. Mainly descriptive and historical in nature, these entries do not seem curiously to give an appropriate account of the complexity and richness of trade cycle theory in England at the time. Even if Jevons’s solar spot theory and Mills ‘credit cycle’ are looming large, no theoretical use of these attempts at finding an endogenous explanation of the periodicity/regularity of cycles are properly reported in any of these entries. These entries seem in fact to display the dominant approach as to the unimportance of crises and hence of a proper theory of crisis ‘which is not of great permanent importance’. As ‘spasmodic symptoms and not symptoms of any serious and continuous diseases’, crises should not be brought ‘under some legislative remedy’. Moreover, the logical impossibility of over production adds to the idea that a systematic theoretical explanation of crises in terms of regular and recurrent cycles is not possible, indeed necessary: ‘events so exceptional defy regulation’ and hence theoretical explanations.

17. FROM CRISES TO CYCLES: TUGAN-BARANOVSKY AND THE BROCKHAUS-EFRON (1895–1915) (FRANÇOIS ALLISSON)
This chapter examines Tugan-Baranovsky's entries on economic crises in the successive editions of Brockhaus-Efron, the landmark encyclopedic dictionary in Tsarist Russia. These entries were published in 1895 and 1915, one year after the first Russian edition of his masterpiece, /Industrial crises in England/ (1894), and one year after its third Russian edition (1914). The evolution of these entries, together with the specific nature of encyclopedic writing (brevity, objectivity), allow to study the development of Tugan-Baranovsky's thought on economic fluctuations. This comparative analysis clearly shows a profound terminological shift from crises to cycles: crises are no longer just periodic accidents, but a normal phase of any capitalist economy.

18. HEINRICH HERKNER: INEQUALITY OF INCOME DISTRIBUTION, OVERCAPITALISATION AND UNDERCONSUMPTION (HARALD HAGEMANN)
In his essay on crises in Conrad’s Handwörterbuch der Staatswissenschaften (1892–1910), Heinrich Herkner, who succeeded Gustav Schmoller on his chair at the University of Berlin as well as in the role of chairman of the Verein für Sozialpolitik, gave a meritorious summary of the different explanations of crises. In his own interpretation Herkner favours theoretical approaches, as those given by Sismondi and Lexis, which put emphasis on the negative consequences of a great inequality of income distribution leading to overcapitalisation and underconsumption. For Herkner an appropriate therapy of the crises problem therefore is strongly linked to the solving of the ‘labour question’ by raising the capability of the masses to consume.

19. WILHELM LEXIS: CRISES AND OVERPRODUCTION (HARALD HAGEMANN)
Wilhelm Lexis, a demographer and outstanding mathematical statistician who is still remembered for the Lexis diagram and his dispersion theory, wrote many articles on consumption, crises and overproduction. For Lexis the relation between production and consumption in the economy is a decisive issue. In contrast to the optimistic views of Say, Ricardo and Mill, Lexis held the view that a general overproduction can arise temporarily in a capitalist economy. He identifies the crisis as the turning point in which the excesses of the former boom are corrected. In his explanation of general overproduction Lexis points out that excess supply on some goods markets reduces labour demand which then lowers the purchasing power of workers and thereby indirectly enhances excess supply of consumption goods. Lexis thus discusses spillover and feedback effects which indicates that the had a general equilibrium system in mind.

20. ARTHUR SPIETHOFF: FROM ECONOMIC CRISES TO BUSINESS CYCLE THEORY (VITANTONIO GIOIA)
The chapter examines the role of the Krisen entry by Spiethoff (Handwőrterbuch der Staatswissenschaften) in the making and the diffusion of the theory of business cycles. Spiethoff’s statement that “cyclical upswings and downswing are the evolutionary forms of a highly developed capitalist system” defines his field of inquiry. His analysis, endowed with an innovative methodological approach, is devoted to a radical critique both against orthodox theory, rooted in Say’s law, and against authors such as Malthus, Sismondi, Lauderdale, etc., who consider the economic crises as symptoms of the pathology of capitalism. His peculiar reflection on the role of overproduction provides a rich explanation of the antithetic stimuli characterizing capitalistic dynamics.

21. KOYNUS’S ‘ECONOMIC CONJUNCTURE’ IN THE GRANAT ENCYCLOPEDIA (VINCENT BARNETT)
This chapter discusses the entry on ‘Economic Conjuncture’ by A.A. Konyus in the Russian/Soviet Encyclopedic Dictionary of the Granat Bibliographical Institute, published in fifty-eight volumes between 1910 and 1948. It summarises the basic approach of the entry as empirically and statistically orientated, being concerned with describing the observable features of business cycles, in direct comparison with similar work undertaken by Wesley Mitchell. It then outlines the use made in the entry of work by both Russian and Western economists. Konyus’s long career from the 1910s to the 1980s is also considered.

22. W.C. MITCHELL, A. BURNS AND T. HAAVELMO ON BUSINESS CYCLES: THE TWO ENCYCLOPAEDIAS OF THE SOCIAL SCIENCES (1930-1935 AND 1968) (FRANCESCO ASSO AND LUCA FIORITO)
This chapter discusses the entries on business cycles contained in the Encyclopaedia of the social sciences (ESS) and the International encyclopaedia of the social sciences (IESS). The ESS and the IESS were published, respectively, in 1930-35 and in 1968 and their treatment of business fluctuations presents both relevant elements of continuity and discontinuity. The major element of continuity is represented by the main entries on business cycles authored by Wesley Clair Mitchell for the ESS and Arthur Burns for the IESS. Both authors were affiliated with the National Bureau of Economic Research and their presentations of business cycles can be seen as two different steps in the development of the so called NBER method. The major element of discontinuity is the inclusion, by the IESS, of a specific entry on “Mathematical models of business cycles” authored by Trygve Haavelmo. Differently from the more “empirical” discussion proposed by Burns, Haavelmo deals with cycles from a strictly analytical point of view, distinguishing between those models which treat the cycle as a consequence of endogenous (closed models) or exogenous disturbances (open models). Moreover, Haavelmo considers the possibility that cyclical behavior may be produced because “the driving force is itself cyclical” (“forced oscillation”) or because “of the particular ways in which the economic system responds to the stimulating forces” (“free oscillations”). The chapter also offers some general presentation of the main features of the two editorial enterprises which hosted these original contributions on cycles.

23. TINBERGEN ON DYNAMICS AND CONJUNCTURE IN STRIDIRON’S BEDRIJFSECONOMISCHE ENCYCLOPEDIE (PETER RODENBURG)
This chapter investigates the way business cycle theory was presented to a bigger audience of non-technical practitioners and businessmen, in economic dictionaries in the Netherlands. In the Netherlands thinking about business cycles was obviously dominated by Jan Tinbergen, as he was by far the greatest authority in this field. The chapter will therefore focus on Jan Tinbergen’s contributions to the Bedrijfseconomische encyclopedie of 1947. The chapter argues that, though the Bedrijfseconomische encyclopedie was perhaps less influential as one might expect on the basis of its considerable seize and big names, it clearly exemplified and popularized Tinbergen’s view on business cycles, even though they were contested in small circles in the Netherlands, most notably by Jan Goudriaan.

24. NIKOLAI KONDRATIEV AND LONG WAVES IN RECENT DICTIONARIES AND ENCYCLOPAEDIAS (FRANCISCO LOUÇÃ)
This chapter summarizes the three stages in the debate on the long waves of capitalist development. Firstly, the debate on business cycles was introduced by Clément Juglar, and almost immediately by a number of statisticians who claimed to have detected longer cycles: Aftalion, Lescure, Parvus, De Wolff, Van Gelderen and Kondratiev, whose works created a new research programme. The second stage was dominated by Schumpeter?s efforts to disseminate the notion of long waves, although others followed him, namely the founders of econometrics, such as Frisch and Tinbergen, or discussed the statistical evidence, as Mitchell and Kuznets. Finally, the modern debates are surveyed as they are evoked in different dictionaries, including the contributions of Solomou, Mensch, Mandel, Reijnders, Tylecote, Freeman and others.

25. POLITICAL BUSINESS CYCLES (JAN-PETER OLTERS)
In surveying the exceptionally extensive and conceptually heterogeneous literature on political business cycles (PBCs), encyclopaedic entries have quite consistently referred to the (presumed) inflationary bias of democratic systems. Internalising voters’ responsiveness to the (expected) state of the economy and designing economic policies on that premise, policymakers are presumed to add elements of instability to the market. While mainstream economics has largely ignored these strategic manipulations of the economy—clearly sub-optimal from a social-welfare perspective—, PBC contributions succeeded in deriving policy recommendations aimed at depoliticising economic (monetary) policy, thus influencing critically the design of economic reforms in recent decades.

26. NONLINEAR BUSINESS CYCLES IN RECENT DICTIONARIES (GIORGIO COLACCHIO)
This chapter surveys the entries dedicated to nonlinear business cycles in both specialised and non specialised dictionaries. In their chronological succession, they reflect the theoretical change that was taking place in the field of economic dynamics: the transition from the study of nonlinear cycles to that of complex dynamics. While in the earliest entries (early 1970s to mid 1980s) the main stress fell on more or less regular cycles, in the latest ones (particularly since the early 1990s) the scene is almost completely dominated by the new issues and techniques involved in the study of nonlinear dynamical systems, and by the problematic relationship between theoretical outcomes and actual time-series data.

27. REAL BUSINESS CYCLES IN RECENT DICTIONARIES (MARC PILKINGTON)
The dictionary entries we set out to analyse in this chapter espouse the definitional aspects and the stylized facts related to real business cycles in the academic literature. We also investigate how these entries describe the very nature of the shocks under scrutiny. It is a well-accepted fact that real business cycle theory performs the conceptual integration of growth and economic fluctuations by renewing the methodology of empirical macroeconomic research, notably through the calibration method. Dictionary entries have accounted for this evolving research methodology in various and sometimes surprising ways. Our select entries shed light on a range of concerns that are necessary to understand the ramifications, the objectives, the methodology and the modern advances in RBC theory. Some of them can even serve as a stepping stone for a renewed framework assessment insofar as they contain implicit critical views as well as a blueprint for further theoretical perspectives of development.

28. BACK TO CRISES. POST-WAR DICTIONARIES AND THE RESILIENCE OF AN OLD CATEGORY (DANIELE BESOMI AND GIORGIO COLACCHIO)
Although the notion of ‘crisis’ was first subsumed under the idea of ‘cycle’ and eventually expurgated from economic terminology, the term continues to exist and occasionally makes it to economic dictionaries. This chapter surveys its usage in post-war dictionaries, beginning from some linguistic and national peculiarities—in particular, the term ‘crises’ is practically interchangeable with ‘cycles’ in French language, while in German crises is used to indicate the Marxist approach as opposed to bourgeois analysis. As to the interpretation of the concept, some writers interpret crises as a pathological deviations from ‘normal’ fluctuations, while some historical and political dictionaries associate crises to qualitative or systemic changes. In economic dictionaries, the entries trying to qualify crises as autonomous from the idea of cycle are extremely rare: we have found only two, one stressing the different logical nature of these concepts, the other emphasizing that crises cannot be encompassed by calculable mechanistic models. We conclude with some reflections on the complex relationship between crises and cycles.

29. BIBLIOGRAPHY OF SPECIALISED DICTIONARIES OF ECONOMICS AND RELATED SUBJECTS (ALSO INCLUDING THE GENERAL ENCYCLOPEDIAS CITED IN THE TEXT) (DANIELE BESOMI)
This chapter offers a general bibliography of dictionaries of economics and related subjects, in so far as they contain a significant portion of economic entries, organized by compilers and by title, reporting all the relevant bibliographic data and retracing the editorial history. This bibliography was compiled by systematically searching library catalogues in the main European languages, with the aid of the secondary literature and existing bibliographies on specialized dictionaries. It contains over 660 titles for a total of more than 1100 editions.