O que é este blog?

Este blog trata basicamente de ideias, se possível inteligentes, para pessoas inteligentes. Ele também se ocupa de ideias aplicadas à política, em especial à política econômica. Ele constitui uma tentativa de manter um pensamento crítico e independente sobre livros, sobre questões culturais em geral, focando numa discussão bem informada sobre temas de relações internacionais e de política externa do Brasil. Para meus livros e ensaios ver o website: www.pralmeida.org. Para a maior parte de meus textos, ver minha página na plataforma Academia.edu, link: https://itamaraty.academia.edu/PauloRobertodeAlmeida;

Meu Twitter: https://twitter.com/PauloAlmeida53

Facebook: https://www.facebook.com/paulobooks

quarta-feira, 20 de junho de 2018

Mister Trump parte em guerra (comercial) - Paulo Roberto de Almeida (Gazeta do Povo)

Meu artigo sobre a "guerra comercial" deliberadamente provocada e deslanchada pelo presidente americano, escrito depois que ele anunciou as primeiras medidas de sobretaxas (de US$ 50 bilhões), mas antes que ele ameaçasse recrudescer em mais US$ 200 bilhões.
Ou seja, o que deveria ser uma ameaça de rusga bilateral, mas com armas de guerra, pode redundar em uma guerra aberta, com equipamento pesado e mobilização de todas as frentes e corpos bélicos, o que fatalmente atingirá outros países, mesmo os "neutros", onde o Brasil gostaria de estar. 
Como nos dois grandes conflitos bélicos do século XX, essas guerras, começadas num contexto regional limitado, logo se transformam em enfrentamentos globais, atingindo todos os países.
Vamos seguir o teatro de operações.
Paulo Roberto de Almeida 

Rumores de guerra comercial já não são

 mais exagerados

Depois da Guerra Fria geopolítica, o que temos hoje é uma Guerra Fria econômica

Gazeta do Povo (Curitiba, 18/06/2018)


Ficou conhecida a frase de Mark Twain, em comentário a jornalistas, quando confrontado a um obituário publicado a seu respeito: “Os rumores sobre a minha morte são grandemente exagerados”. O mesmo poderia ser dito, até recentemente, sobre as ameaças de uma guerra comercial, continuamente anunciada pelos jornais nos últimos meses, mas que ainda não tinha sido aberta de verdade. Não mais, agora já é um fato: o presidente Trump anunciou sua decisão de impor sobretaxas a produtos exportados pela China num valor aproximado a US$ 50 bilhões. A China anunciou imediatamente que iria retaliar por um montante equivalente, alvejando produtos da exportação americana para a China. Ou seja, a declaração de guerra já foi expedida: resta ver como serão feitos os movimentos dos batalhões respectivos das políticas comerciais nacionais.
Nunca foi tão importante estar bem informado.Sua assinatura financia o bom jornalismo.
Em primeiro lugar, é preciso ficar claro que o anúncio americano não atinge apenas produtos chineses exportados para os EUA – muitos dos quais, por sinal, podem ser feitos na China, mas sob licença americana, ou seja, servindo aos interesses das empresas e dos consumidores americanos –, e sim os fluxos de comércio dessas linhas de produtos de quaisquer origens e destinações. A explicação é que as sobretaxas aplicadas pelas autoridades aduaneiras americanas atingem produtos, não fornecedores, como sempre ocorre com as salvaguardas (que são diferentes de outros mecanismos de defesa comercial, como pode ser o antidumping, que foca um fornecedor determinado).
Trump justificou a imposição dessas medidas como sendo por motivos de “segurança nacional”, o que é altamente discutível, e poderá ser facilmente desmentido por uma investigação no âmbito da OMC (como fatalmente ocorrerá a partir de reclamações de parceiros prejudicados, e não apenas a China, como já revelado no caso do alumínio e do aço). O problema é que uma investigação na OMC, e a consequente condenação de uma medida claramente violadora do Código de Salvaguardas do Acordo Geral de Tarifas Aduaneiras e Comércio (GATT), costuma demorar mais de ano e meio, talvez dois anos, para ser concluída, e a única coisa que o painel arbitral conseguirá aprovar será, provavelmente, uma autorização para retaliações legais dos atingidos, o que não resolve o problema para ninguém, uma vez que o comércio não se faz como mera expressão da vontade, e sim por razões de preço e qualidade. Assim, as contramedidas conseguem apenas agravar o problema original.
O comércio não se faz como mera expressão da vontade, e sim por razões de preço e qualidade
Uma coisa precisa ficar clara: os déficits comerciais dos EUA, atualmente gigantescos, não são uma novidade, mas um fenômeno praticamente crônico há várias décadas, ainda que eles tenham conhecido flutuações cíclicas – ao sabor das paridades cambiais e dos ciclos econômicos nas principais economias do planeta –, assim como o imenso desequilíbrio no intercâmbio comercial com a China, crescente desde o final do século passado. Dos quase 900 bilhões de dólares de déficit na balança comercial dos EUA, um terço é realizado por exportações chinesas em excesso de suas importações da mesma origem, uma conta que é largamente compensada pelos ganhos obtidos pelos EUA a partir dos serviços, rendas do capital (em diversas rubricas) investido sob a forma de investimento direto ou de aplicações de portfólio.
Sorry, the video player failed to load.(Error Code: 101104)
A concepção primitiva que o presidente americano mantém a respeito do comércio internacional faz com que ele veja um “prejuízo” para o seu país cada vez que se manifesta um déficit bilateral, o que é absolutamente considerado uma insensatez por qualquer economista sério. O déficit geograficamente considerado a partir do território dos EUA é amplamente compensado pelas exportações das empresas americanas ao redor do mundo, como resultado de décadas de investimentos diretos em quase todos os quadrantes do planeta. Muitos outros países exibem balanças comerciais cronicamente deficitárias, mas cobrindo essas “lacunas” por retornos em outros capítulos do balanço de pagamentos, o que é exatamente o caso dos EUA, que justamente exporta sua moeda nacional ao resto do mundo. O euro não confirmou até o momento as expectativas de que poderia representar parte substancial das reservas nacionais e dos fluxos de pagamentos de fatores para um volume mais significativo dos intercâmbios mundiais.
O Brasil, por exemplo, país notoriamente protecionista, sempre manteve um estrito controle sobre os fluxos de sua balança comercial, uma vez que esses saldos são o único recurso de que dispõe para compensar uma balança de serviços cronicamente deficitária, mas justamente com os EUA acumula saldos negativos desde vários anos, o que não o impediu de ser também atingido pelas salvaguardas de Trump sobre o aço e o alumínio, cabendo-lhe apenas aceitar as sobretaxas (para o alumínio) ou redução dos volumes exportados, as chamadas “restrições voluntárias”, claramente ilegais aos olhos da OMC. Registre-se, desde já, que as mesmas medidas foram aplicadas contra os parceiros americanos do Nafta, Canadá e México, o que é propriamente incrível, pois entre os três países deveria vigorar o livre comércio.
A China saberá responder adequadamente – o que não quer dizer sem prejuízos para si mesma e outros países, entre eles o Brasil – a esse novo desafio lançado por um presidente claramente equivocado tanto no plano conceitual quanto no aspecto prático. Os primeiros prejudicados serão as empresas, os consumidores e os trabalhadores americanos, de uma ampla gama de setores (e segundo uma escolha chinesa visando atingir em primeiro lugar os eleitores de Trump em determinados estados). Pode-se, também, colocar esse complicado contencioso num quadro mais amplo, marcado pela irresistível ascensão da China a certa preeminência internacional, sobretudo no campo econômico, e pelo declínio relativo dos EUA como superpotência indiscutível em todas as vertentes do “grande jogo” geopolítico.
De fato, depois da Guerra Fria geopolítica conhecida durante as quatro décadas em que vigorou a bipolaridade EUA-União Soviética, o que temos hoje é uma Guerra Fria econômica, num contexto de crescente multipolaridade a partir da emergência de potências ascendentes fora do eixo norte-atlântico tradicional. Tanto em termos táticos, quando no plano estratégico, a China deve sagrar-se vencedora desse embate, na medida em que possuiu uma visão clara de quais são os seus objetivos permanentes, a despeito mesmo de suas práticas claramente oportunistas no âmbito comercial. O presidente Trump parece completamente perdido na condução de sua política comercial, uma vez que promete impor novas sanções, pelo dobro do valor, caso a China responda às suas medidas não apenas irracionais, como claramente ilegais segundo as regras da OMC.
O que vai ocorrer? Provavelmente uma crise inédita nas relações econômicas internacionais, provocada por um personagem também inédito na governança da maior potência planetária. Os americanos já “inventaram” a Lei de Murphy – o que pode dar errado, dará, da pior forma possível – e também conhecem a “lei das consequências involuntárias”, que é exatamente o que acontecerá neste caso. O presidente Trump vai conseguir prejudicar não só os seus próprios eleitores, como todos os cidadãos, dezenas de empresas americanas e o papel dos EUA na manutenção da ordem econômica mundial. Parece muito, mas ainda é pouco para um personagem nitidamente desequilibrado, o primeiro a governar o seu país – e a pretender mandar no mundo – a partir de seus tweets diários, já na altura de algumas dezenas de milhares. Podemos esperar novos e tresloucados gestos nas próximas semanas e meses. Parafraseando o título de uma antiga série da TV americana: incrível, mas verdadeiro!
Paulo Roberto de Almeida é diplomata de carreira, professor universitário e especialista do Instituto Millenium.

terça-feira, 19 de junho de 2018

Caso raro: um ex-ministro israelense espionando para o Iran

MANCHETES DE ÚLTIMA HORA



ALTA TRAIÇÃO: EX-MINISTRO ISRAELENSE ACUSADO DE ESPIONAR PARA O IRÃ
O ex-ministro Gonen Segev foi indiciado na semana passada por espionar o Estado de Israel para o Irã, disseram nesta segunda-feira a Polícia de Israel e o Shin Bet. Segev foi acusado de espionagem, ajudando um inimigo em tempo de guerra, bem como fornecendo informações para o inimigo. Segev, o ex-ministro da energia e infra-estrutura, é suspeito de fornecer informações sobre a indústria de energia de Israel, sites de segurança no país, instalações estratégicas e funcionários políticos e militares, entre outras coisas. O ex-ministro, que vive na Nigéria nos últimos anos, tentou entrar na Guiné Equatorial em maio de 2018, onde foi impedido de entrar por causa de seu passado criminoso e, conseqüentemente, transferido para Israel. Ele foi preso e interrogado pelo Shin Bet e pela Polícia de Israel depois que a inteligência reunida sobre ele levantou a suspeita de que ele estava em contato com a inteligência iraniana e auxiliando-os em suas ativida des contra Israel. A investigação descobriu que Segev foi recrutado e foi operado como um agente da inteligência iraniana. Ele foi contatado pela primeira vez por funcionários da embaixada iraniana na Nigéria, em 2012 e, em um estágio posterior, viajou duas vezes ao Irã para reuniões com seus manipuladores - embora estivesse plenamente ciente de que pertenciam à inteligência iraniana. Ao longo dos anos como agente iraniano, Segev reuniu-se com seus manipuladores em apartamentos e hotéis em todo o mundo, o que ele disse aos interrogadores que ele acredita serem usados ??para atividade secreta iraniana. Ele também recebeu um sistema de comunicações criptografadas para ocultar a troca de mensagens entre ele e seus manipuladores. Para obter a informação que lhe foi pedida por seus manipuladores iranianos, Segev manteve contatos com israelenses que têm ligações com a segurança, a defesa e as relações exteriores de Israel. Ele trabalhou para colocar as autoridades israelenses em c ontato com elementos de inteligência iraniana, enquanto tentava enganá-los e apresentar os iranianos como empresários inócuos. Segev foi eleito pela primeira vez para o 13º Knesset, em 1992, como parte do partido Tzomet de Rafael Eitan, onde ele atuou como MK de oposição e membro do Comitê de Finanças do Knesset. Em fevereiro de 1994, Segev e dois outros MKs se separaram do Tzomet e formaram a facção Yiud. Em janeiro de 1995, Segev se tornou o ministro de energia e infraestrutura do governo de Yitzhak Rabin e continuou ocupando o cargo no governo de Shimon Peres depois do assassinato de Rabin. Depois de sua carreira política, Segev se tornou um homem de negócios. Ele foi preso em abril de 2004 por tentar contrabandear milhares de comprimidos de ecstasy de Amsterdã para Israel, alegando que eles achavam que eram M & M's. Ele também foi acusado de estender ilegalmente seu passaporte diplomático com um lápis para evitar ser submetido a uma busca por autoridades aeroportuárias holandesas.

Brazil as a Failing State (or, is it already a Failed State?) - Paulo R Almeida (Estoril Political Forum 2017)

Na próxima semana estarei no 26. Estoril Political Forum, organizado pelo IEP-UCP, como informei nesta postagem, já colocando o meu texto à disposição: 

https://diplomatizzando.blogspot.com/2018/06/de-la-non-democratie-en-amerique-latine.html

No ano passado, no 25. Estoril Political Forum, quando ali fui pela primeira vez, estávamos a um ano do "golpe" do impeachment, como proclamavam os companheiros, esquecendo que, pela sua extraordinária incompetência e gigantesca corrupção, foram eles que provocaram a Grande Destruição, a maior recessão de nossa história e a mais ampla deterioração das instituições públicas no Brasil, sem falar do descalabro moral, que se disseminou em todos os espaços públicos (e ate privados).
Nessa situação, eu me perguntava se o Brasil era um país em estado falimentar, ou se ele já era um Estado falido.
Aqui está o início do texto, o resto podendo ser lido na plataforma Academia.edu: 
https://www.academia.edu/36866539/Brazil_as_a_Failing_State_or_is_it_already_a_Failed_State_-_Estoril_Political_Forum_2017

Brazil as a Failing State


Paulo Roberto de Almeida
Political sociologist, university professor (Uniceub)
 [Estoril Political Forum; Panel Brazil, June 27, 2017]


1. Brazil: the democracy that failed
2. The scenario built by the new Barbarians
3. A schizophrenic Constitution, deepening our failures
4. The conquest of the State by the political mafia of PT
5. What’s the way out of this?
6. Reforms: what is possible and what is impossible?

1. Brazil: the democracy that failed
I started this draft text, for the purpose of delivering an oral statement, some three months ago, around March, just after having accepted the invitation by the organizers to take part in the Brazil panel of the Estoril Political Forum. At that moment, the second title was not the question of Brazil being already a Failed State, but just a doubt, expressed with this almost affirmative interrogation: “will it become a Failed State?” It may be the case, judging by recent developments in the last few weeks, in the political, judicial, and police spheres, all of them very busy with too many cases of corruption, protests, and institutional impasses. So, in less than three months, I had to rephrase and strengthen my title, just to emphasize the true state of political affairs in my country: the scenario is deteriorating rapidly, to say the least.
With this new introduction, in the form of the above paragraph, I will have to be direct, sharp and may be unduly severe: Brazil is, if not already a Failed State, at least a Failing State, in many dimensions of this concept. In fact, its political system, under whatever criteria we may choose, has already failed. This is the result not only of the kleptocratic behavior exhibited by some of its members, but also because of the very well known rent-seeking attitude of many, if not all, representatives of the Brazilian elites, entrepreneurs, politicians, trade-unionists and the rest. The present scenario is on the verge of anomie, not only because of episodic factors, such as the current political crisis or economic recession, but because of a structural deterioration of Brazilian institutions, despite an apparent resiliency of its formally democratic architecture. The true Brazilian crisis nowadays is of a moral order, the very glue that maintains a nation united behind its values and principles: Brazilian citizenship today does not trust anymore any of the three branches of government, the Executive, the Legislative and the Judiciary.
Brazil is a deteriorating polity that, in view of the lack of any real consensus around the necessary reforms in its ailing institutions, promises to continue to be weakening gradually for the next few years, towards its first two hundred years of existence as an independent nation, and irrespective of the general elections in 2018. Indeed, in 2022, income per head of the average Brazilian will be the same, perhaps even less, than its level attained ten years before; the state of its public debt will be on the verge of bankruptcy, if not already insolvent; and the ominous fragmentation of its political system will be worsening to the point of a governance disaster. 
Those are threatening features that pale when confronted with the moral dereliction of our so-called political elites, together with the promiscuous capitalists and bankers that have been funding the former, in a rare neglect of duty (perhaps it was intentional) for a country formally modern, proud of its democratic institutions, and possessing one truly sophisticated State among developing countries of the Western Hemisphere, if not in the global South. Has Brazil become a toxic State?
(...)
Ler a íntegra aqui: 

Na parte final, eu listo aquelas que me pareciam ser as reformas possíveis (otimista que eu era, ou seria pessimista?) e as outras, impossíveis. Aqui: 

Possible reforms:  
1) A radical shrinking of the weight of the State over the productive life of the nation, starting by the reduction to half in the number of ministries, with a proportional elimination of a wide range of public entities. Decrease in the Kafka-like bureaucracy of the Federal Revenue Service. End of any type of privileges linked to public functions.
2) Reduction and simplification of the fiscal charge, which is very difficult because of various levels of taxation in the federation and regional differences in fiscal repartition of the receipts; therefore, the reform could start by a linear decrease in the various rates, for instance 0.5% annually during a ten-year period, while a discussion on the quality and amount of each type of taxation, and its appropriation by states and municipalities, can take place in a orderly manner.
3) A new fiscal deal: suppression of the unconstitutional figure of conditional budget allocation by the Executive, as well as pork barrel individual additions to the budget, which has to applied and implemented exactly as approved by the Parliament; 
4) Elimination of the complete machine for governmental self-propaganda, only allowed information campaigns with a true finality of public order (vaccination, and natural catastrophes, for instance); communication is well served by private channels.
5) Resumption of a general reform in the social security systems, unification of the common and public sector schemes, elimination of all residual privileges, and the establishment of a sustainable intergeneration mechanism, compatible with the moving demography and the sectorial financing of the new system.
6) A complete revision in the National Health Service, nowadays working under a fictional non-paid, universal access system, towards a market-based, multiple system of insurance companies, with subsidies only for the confirmed low income strata.

Impossible reforms:  
1) A political reform aimed at the complete elimination of the Party Fund, a State sponsored stipend to every party recognized as such by the Electoral Tribunal, which is an inducement to the creation of new legends, and the fragmentation of the existing parties, giving financial support to “for-rent-parties” (or, an electoral business of the worst sort); current system allows a total segregation between the party machine and the electorate, which is, in sum, a rent-seeking approach to politics. No public financing of campaigns of any kind: parties are private law undertakings.
2) Immediate extinction of 50% of all commissioned jobs in the public sector, in all levels and spheres of governmental activities, with a concomitant establishment of a parliamentary and executive commission designed to reduce and align the remaining jobs, to be filled by open meritocratic recruitment, without the current stability at entrance; complete interdiction of reciprocal nepotism and other forms of preference.
3) Education: creation of a new class of teachers and professors, paid according to merit and benchmark results, without stability, but with a constant program for training and capacitation, proportionate to remuneration.
4) Privatization of every public or state company not linked to an essential and exclusive public service (defense and justice, for instance). 
5) Elimination of all tax and fiscal exemptions, and other privileges, linked to the so-called “religious entities”, now turned into a thriving “industry”. The same applies to trade unions, another “big industry”: elimination of the “syndical taxation”, complete freedom of association, no public resources whatsoever for the “centrals”. 

This is my personal list for reform in Brazil, that could be integrated to an agenda for reform during the next few years, if – and that’s a Big If – there could be any chance of real consensus among political elites and entrepreneurs in that direction. We all know that reforms, in general, are always difficult, as Tocqueville recognized in relation to the transition from the Ancien Régimeto a constitutional system in his own country, France. If not implemented as a result of a consensual governance outlook among the governing or dominant elites, reforms become disruptive, and are usually initiated after a deep societal crisis, which is perhaps not yet the case in Brazil, at least not in the same extension that those that occurred in recently in Greece, in Argentina, and currently in Venezuela. 
Could Brazil descend into the chaos that those countries were, or are today? Not of this kind, at least in the foreseeable future, although disruptive events cannot be at all excluded. What instead could happen in Brazil would be a protracted crisis made of low growth, partial or imperfect sectorial reforms, and a clear loss of legitimacy of the three branches of government. Worse, the current political mess in Brazil offers plenty of raw materials for all types of dark humor, that is political jokes of a derogatory nature against government and State institutions. In fact, political humorists in Brazil do not need to invent or create anything, do not have to have any inspiration for their jokes: all they need is offered on total freedom and gratuity by the official institutions and their representatives. To be true, those public figures constitute an unfair competition and an informal concurrence to professional humorists. That’s not a joke, it’s a political tragedy!

Paulo Roberto de Almeida
Brasília, June 12, 2017
Divulgado no blog Diplomatizzando(26/06/2017; link: http://diplomatizzando.blogspot.pt/2017/06/brasil-existe-uma-crise-da-democracia.html),

segunda-feira, 18 de junho de 2018

Capitalism explained by Ludwig von Mises - Dan Sanchez

Capitalism Encapsulated: Mises in Four Easy Pieces

Ludwig von Mises boiled down capitalism to the essential features that he believed every citizen needed to know.
Dan Sanchez
 
Mises.org, June 17, 2018
One day in 1959, hundreds of students, educators, and grandees filled the enormous lecture hall of the University of Buenos Aires to capacity, overflowing into two neighboring rooms. Argentina was still reeling from the reign of populist presidente, Juan Perón, who had been ousted four years before. Perón’s economic policies were supposed to empower and uplift the people but only created poverty and chaos. Perhaps the men and women in that auditorium were ready for a different message. They certainly got one.
A dignified old man stepped before them and delivered a bold, bracing message: what truly empowers and uplifts the people is capitalism, the much-maligned economic system that emerges from private ownership of the means of production.
This man, Ludwig von Mises, had been the world’s leading champion of capitalism for half a century, so his message was finely honed. Not only a creative genius but also a superb educator, he boiled down capitalism to the essential features that he believed every citizen needed to know. As his wife Margit recollected, the effect on the crowd was invigorating. Having spent years in an intellectual atmosphere of stale, stagnant ideas:
The audience reacted as if a window had been opened and fresh air allowed to breeze through the rooms.
This lecture was the first in a series, the transcriptions of which are collected in the book Economic Policy: Thoughts for Today and Tomorrow, edited by Margit.

Life (and Death) Before Capitalism

To demonstrate in his lecture how revolutionary the advent of capitalism was in world history, Mises contrasted it with what he called the feudalistic principles of production during Europe’s earlier ages.
The feudal system was characterized by productive rigidity. Power, law, and custom prohibited individuals from leaving their station in the economic system and from entering another. Peasant serfs were irrevocably bound to the land they tilled, which in turn was inalienably tied to their noble lords. Princes and urban guilds strictly limited entry into whole industries and precluded the emergence of new ones. Almost every productive role in society was a caste. This productive rigidity translated into socio-economic rigidity, or “social immobility.” As Mises reminded his Argentine audience:
…a man’s social status was fixed from the beginning to the end of his life; he inherited it from his ancestors, and it never changed. If he was born poor, he always remained poor, and if he was born rich—a lord or a duke—he kept his dukedom and the property that went with it for the rest of his life.
Over 90 percent of the population was consigned to food production so as to precariously eke out sustenance for their own families and contribute to the banquets of their domineering lords. They also had to make their own clothing and other consumers’ goods at home. So, production was largely autarkic and non-specialized. As Mises highlighted, the small amount of specialized manufacturing that existed in the towns was devoted largely to the production of luxury goods for the elite.
From the High Middle Ages onward, production in western Europe was higher and the average person much less likely to be a chattel slave than during antiquity and the Dark Ages. But the economic system was still fixed and moribund; the common man had no hope of progressing beyond a life teetering between bare subsistence and starvation.
It was then and there that capitalism entered the scene, saving the lives of millions, and vastly improving the lives of millions more. 

And in the 18th century, in the Netherlands and England, said Mises, multitudes were about to go over the Malthusian ledge, because the population had grown beyond the land then available to employ and sustain them.
It was then and there that capitalism entered the scene, saving the lives of millions, and vastly improving the lives of millions more.
Four key distinguishing features of capitalism can be gleaned from Mises’s lecture. What follows is an exposition of those features, which can be thought of as, to paraphrase Richard Feynman, "Mises in four easy pieces."
It is important to note that, as Mises fully noted elsewhere, what emerged in the 18th century and developed subsequently was never a purely free market. So, the following characteristics have never been universal. But these features did come into play far more extensively in this period than ever before.

1. Dynamic Production

Under what Mises called “capitalistic principles of production,” feudal productive rigidity is replaced by productive flexibility and free entry. There are no legal privileges protecting anyone’s place in the system of production. Lords and guilds cannot exclude new entrants and innovations. And an upstart enterpriser’s capital, products, and proceeds are secure from the cupidity of princes and the jealousy of incumbents.
Free entry/exit is the logical corollary of liberty: inviolate self-ownership and private property. 

Of course, free entry amounts to very little without the corresponding right of free exit. With capitalism, peasants are free to leave their fields and former masters for opportunities in the towns. And proprietors are free to sell or hire out their plots of land and other resources to the highest bidder. (Although, during the transition between feudal and capitalist production, it really should have been the peasants doing the selling and hiring out, as they were owed restitution never delivered for their past serfdom and expropriation.)
Free entry/exit is the logical corollary of liberty: inviolate self-ownership and private property. It is the freedom of an individual to put his labor and earnings to whatever productive use he finds advantageous, irrespective of the pretenses to privilege of vested interests.
Under capitalism, no longer can nobles rely on a captive labor force and “customer” base, or enjoy the impossibility of having resources bid away by more efficient producers. No longer can these robber barons turned landed barons rest on such laurels of past armed conquest.
Free entry/exit imposes the stimulus and discipline of competition on producers, impelling them to strive to outdo each other in satisfying potential customers. 

Mises identified resentment of this fact as a prime source of anti-capitalism, which thus originated, not with the proletariat, but with the landed aristocracy. He cited the consternation of the Prussian Junkers of Germany over the Landflucht or “flight from the countryside” of their peasant underlings. And he related a colorful story of how Otto von Bismarck, that prince of Junkers who founded the welfare state (with the express purpose of co-opting the masses), grumbled about a worker who left Bismarck’s estate for the higher wages and pleasant beer gardens of Berlin.
Under capitalism, no longer can tradesmen idle in old methods and old markets. To do so is impossible in a world in which any man with savings and gumption is a potential underseller and overbidder. Industry incumbents also loathe the competition, so their special pleading is another major source of anti-capitalist rhetoric.
Free entry/exit imposes the stimulus and discipline of competition on producers, impelling them to strive to outdo each other in satisfying potential customers. As Mises proclaimed in Buenos Aires:
The development of capitalism consists in everyone’s having the right to serve the customer better and/or more cheaply.
Production, formerly adrift in the standing water of feudalistic stagnation, sets sail under capitalistic dynamism, driven by the bracing winds of competition.

2. Consumer Sovereignty

When producers vie with each other to better serve customers, they unavoidably act more and more like devoted servants of those customers. This is true of even the biggest and wealthiest producers. As Mises brilliantly expressed it:
In talking about modern captains of industry and leaders of big business… they call a man a “chocolate king” or a “cotton king” or an “automobile king.” Their use of such terminology implies that they see practically no difference between the modern heads of industry and those feudal kings, dukes or lords of earlier days. But the difference is in fact very great, for a chocolate king does not rule at all, he serves. He does not reign over conquered territory, independent of the market, independent of his customers. The chocolate king—or the steel king or the automobile king or any other king of modern industry—depends on the industry he operates and on the customers he serves. This “king” must stay in the good graces of his subjects, the consumers; he loses his “kingdom” as soon as he is no longer in a position to give his customers better service and provide it at lower cost than others with whom he must compete.
With capitalism, just as producers play the role of servant, customers play the role of master or sovereign: in a figurative sense, of course. It is their wishes that hold sway, as producers strive to grant them. And strive they must if they want to succeed in business. For, just as a sovereign of the ancien regime was free to withhold favor from one courtier and bestow it upon another, the “sovereign” customer is free to take his business elsewhere.
This relation is even expressed in the language we use to describe commerce. Customers are patrons who patronizeshops and other sellers. These sellers say, “thank you for your business” or patronage, and insist that “the customer is always right.” The polite, respectful deference formerly given by the ancient Roman cliens (client) to his patronus(patron) is now instead given by the producer to his customer/patron, except generally in a much more self-respecting and less groveling manner.
Thus, with capitalism, it is the consumers who hold ultimate sway over all production. 

If the customer is himself also a producer on the market, he must pay forward that same solicitousness and deference to his own customers, lest he lose their business to competitors. Thus, his desires for goods from his eagerly attentive suppliers are shaped by his own eagerness to fulfill the desires of his own customers. Therefore, the higher-order producer, by striving to make his customer happy, indirectly strives to make his customer’s customers happy as well.
This series terminates with the customers who have no customers: namely, the consumers, who are therefore the “engine” of this “train” of final causation. Thus, with capitalism, it is the consumers who hold ultimate sway over all production. Mises referred to this fundamental characteristic of capitalism as, speaking figuratively, consumer sovereignty.
Again, this is constrained to the extent that state intervention hampers capitalism. “Leaders of big business” can and often do use the state to acquire powers and privileges that enable them to flout the wishes of consumers and acquire wealth through domination instead of service.

3. Mass Production for the Masses

In a lecture by David Gordon I once attended, the scholar drew from his limitless reservoir of scholarly anecdotes to relate that Maurice Dobb, a British economist and communist, replied to Mises’s point about consumer sovereignty by averring that this feature of capitalism hardly does the common man any good, since the most significant consumers are the wealthiest. Dobb’s mistake, of course, is to neglect the fact that the relative importance of single consumers is not the issue here. The combined purchasing power of the preponderance of typically wealthy consumers vastly outstrips that of the atypically wealthy.
Therefore, as Mises pointed out, the capitalist’s main route to becoming one of those few wealthy consumers of extraordinary means is through mass-producing wares that cater to the masses of consumers of ordinary means. Even a small per-unit profit margin, if multiplied millions or billions of times, adds up to some serious dough. Boutique enterprises catering only to the elite, as feudal era manufacturers did, simply cannot compare. And that is why, as Mises informed the stunned Perónistas:
Big business, the target of the most fanatic attacks by the so-called leftists, produces almost exclusively to satisfy the wants of the masses. Enterprises producing luxury goods solely for the well-to-do can never attain the magnitude of big businesses.
That is why, as Mises never tired of saying, capitalism is a system of mass production for the masses. It is overwhelmingly the masses of “regular folk” who are the sovereign consumers whose wishes are the guiding stars of capitalist production.
Capitalism flipped feudalism on its head. With feudalism, it was the elite (the landed aristocracy) whose will dominated the masses (the enserfed peasants). With capitalism, it is the wishes of the masses (ordinary consumers) that hold sway over the productive activity of the entrepreneurial elite, from retail giants to dot-com millionaires.
As Mises’s address implied, the yearned-for “people power” always promised by demagogues like Perón, but which invariably turns to ashes in the mouths of the masses, as it did with the Argentines, is the natural result of capitalism, a system so often derided as “economic royalism.”
Imagine his audience’s surprise!
With capitalism, the working people really do hold ultimate sway over the means of production. 

But the full truth that Mises was imparting was even more surprising than that. Not only does capitalism fulfill the broken promises of economic populism, but, as Gordon remarked in his lecture, it also follows through on the more specific promise offered by syndicalists and Marxian socialists: worker control over the means of production. That is because, as Mises stressed in his lecture, the vast majority of the masses of ordinary “sovereign” consumers are also workers.
With capitalism, the working people really do hold ultimate sway over the means of production. They just don’t do it in their role as workers but in their role as consumers. They exert their sway in checkout aisles and website shopping carts, and not in the halls of labor unions, syndicates, soviets (revolutionary councils of workers), or a “dictatorship of the proletariat” that reigns in their name while it rides on their backs.
Capitalism has the charming arrangement of empowering the working person, while still preserving economic sanity by placing means (factors of production, like labor) at the service of ends (consumer demand).

4. Prosperity for the People

Capitalism not only empowers the working person, but uplifts him.
Capitalism, as its name implies, is characterized by capital investment, which was the solution to the crisis of how the marginal millions of 18th-century England and the Netherlands were to integrate into the economy and survive.
Labor alone cannot produce; it needs to be applied to complementary material resources. If, with given production techniques, there is not enough land in the economy to employ all hands, then those hands must be placed upon capital goods, if the connected mouths are to eat. During the Industrial Revolution, such capital goods were lifelines that the owners of new factories threw to countless economic castaways and that pulled them from the abyss and back into the division of labor that kept their lives afloat.
Knowing this truth of the matter, Mises was rightly appalled at the anti-capitalist agitators who “falsified history” (Gordon identified Thomas Carlyle and Friedrich Engels as among the worst offenders) to spread the now dominant myth that capitalism was a bane to the working poor. He set the issue right with passion:
Of course, from our viewpoint, the workers’ standard of living was extremely low; conditions under early capitalism were absolutely shocking, but not because the newly developed capitalistic industries had harmed the workers. The people hired to work in factories had already been existing at a virtually subhuman level.
The famous old story, repeated hundreds of times, that the factories employed women and children and that these women and children, before they were working in factories, had lived under satisfactory conditions, is one of the greatest falsehoods of history. The mothers who worked in the factories had nothing to cook with; they did not leave their homes and their kitchens to go into the factories, they went into factories because they had no kitchens, and if they had a kitchen they had no food to cook in those kitchens. And the children did not come from comfortable nurseries. They were starving and dying. And all the talk about the so-called unspeakable horror of early capitalism can be refuted by a single statistic: precisely in these years in which British capitalism developed, precisely in the age called the Industrial Revolution in England, in the years from 1760 to 1830, precisely in those years the population of England doubled, which means that hundreds or thousands of children—who would have died in preceding times—survived and grew to become men and women.
And as Mises further explained, capitalism not only saves lives, but it vastly improves them. That is because capitalism is also characterized by capital accumulation (which is why Mises embraced the term, in spite of it originating from its enemies as an epithet), which is the result of cumulative saving and perpetual reinvestmentbeing unleashed by greater security of property from meddlesome laws as well as grasping princes and parliaments. Capital accumulation means ever-growing labor productivity, which in turn means ever-rising real wages for the worker.
These higher wages are the conduits through which workers acquire the purchasing power that crowns them with consumer sovereignty. And they are no petty sovereigns either. Thanks to his capital-enhanced high productivity, a modern worker’s wage-powered consumer demand guides the deployment of a globe-spanning, dizzying plethora of sophisticated machines, factories, vehicles, raw materials, and other resources, as well as the voluntary labor of the other workers who use them, all of which conspire to churn out a cornucopia of quality household staples, marvelous devices, amazing experiences, and other consumers’ goods and services for the worker to choose from for his delectation. Purchasing such goods with his higher wages is how the worker claims his portion of the greater abundance, which approximatesto his own capital-enhanced contribution to it.
And higher wages are not the only way that the average working person can enrich himself through capitalism. Especially since the advent of investment funds, he can supplement and, upon retirement, even replace his wage income with interest and profit by putting his high-wage-fed savings to work and partaking in capital investment himself.
Because of these characteristics, as Mises proclaimed to those assembled:
[Capitalism] has, within a comparatively short time, transformed the whole world. It has made possible an unprecedented increase in world population.
He returned to the subject of England for one of the more paradigmatic examples of this:
In 18th-century England, the land could support only 6 million people at a very low standard of living. Today more than 50 million people enjoy a much higher standard of living than even the rich enjoyed during the 18th century. And today’s standard of living in England would probably be still higher, had not a great deal of the energy of the British been wasted in what were, from various points of view, avoidable political and military "adventures."
In one of those wonderful flashes of dry wit that would illuminate his discourse from time to time, Mises urged his auditors that, should they ever meet an anti-capitalist hailing from England, they should ask him:
…how do you know that you are the one out of ten who would have lived in the absence of capitalism? The mere fact that you are living today is proof that capitalism has succeeded, whether or not you consider your own life very valuable.
Mises furthermore cited the more general and clearly evident fact that:
There is no Western, capitalistic country in which the conditions of the masses have not improved in an unprecedented way.
And in the decades following his speech, the conditions of the masses improved incredibly in non-Western countries (like China) who partially opened up to capitalism as well.
Mises concluded his talk by urging his Argentine fellows to seize the day and strive for the economic liberation that would unleash the wonderworks of capitalism, and not to sit and wait for an economic miracle:
But you have to remember that, in economic policies, there are no miracles. You have read in many newspapers and speeches, about the so-called German economic miracle—the recovery of Germany after its defeat and destruction in the Second World War. But this was no miracle. It was the application of the principles of the free market economy, of the methods of capitalism, even though they were not applied completely in all respects. Every country can experience the same “miracle” of economic recovery, although I must insist that economic recovery does notcome from a miracle; it comes from the adoption of—and is the result of—sound economic policies.

Conclusion

If the subsequent policies adopted in Argentina, South America, and the world are any indication, Mises’s message, as lucid and affecting as it was, did not propagate far beyond the auditorium walls that day. Perhaps in the age of camera phones, YouTube, and social media, it would have. But his brilliant encapsulation of the beneficence and beauty of capitalism did not dissipate vainly into the Argentine air. Thanks to his Margit and to institutions that spread his works online (like FEE, the Mises Institute, and Liberty Fund), his message was preserved for the ages and is now only a mouse click away for billions.
Ludwig von Mises can still save the world by posthumously teaching its people the unknown truth about the inherently populist nature of capitalism in a way which speaks to their hopes and longings: that private property means dynamic production, which means a competitive, consumer-steered economy, which means a production system geared toward improving the lives of the masses, which first means widespread succor and ultimately ever-rising prosperity for the people of the world.