sábado, 13 de julho de 2013

Trade integration in eight figures - Arvind Subramanian and Martin Kessler

REALTIME ECONOMIC ISSUES WATCH

by Arvind Subramanian and Martin Kessler 
Peterson Institute of International Economics, July 12th, 2013 

In this short post (based on our recent paper), we present eight attributes of the current phase of trade integration which began towards the end of the last millennium.
Hyperglobalization
Since 1870, there have been four phases of trade integration, as figure 1 shows. The first three were (1) globalization of the late 19th century; (2) the collapse of globalization in the Great Depression; (3) reglobalization after World War II. In this fourth phase of hyperglobalization, trade has grown substantially faster than world GDP and now represents about a third of world GDP. Trade in merchandise will soon reach twice what it was at the peak of the first globalization (just prior to World War I). This is true whether trade is measured in gross or value-added terms. (A chart on global foreign direct investment flows would show a similar trend.)
Figure 1 World exports as share of GDP, 1870–2011 (current dollars)


Sources: Klasing and Milionis (2013) for historical data, WTO for 1960–2011, Johnson and Noguera (2012) for value-added adjustment.

Dematerializing Globalization
Trade is becoming less about stuff and more about, well, fluff. But because services (fluff) are not traded directly, but embodied in goods which cross borders, their footprint is only visible when trade is properly measured (in value-added terms). Under this measure, services represented 43 percent of global trade in 2008 against 29 percent in 1980 (figure 2). Services are also becoming more tradable.
Figure 2 Exports of goods and services, in gross and value-added terms


Sources: World Development Indicators, Johnson and Noguera (2012) for value-added adjustment.

Democratic Globalization
Hyperglobalization is not confined to a few countries. It is not occurring because some large countries are emsbracing trade. It is a very broad phenomenon occurring across all countries, rich and poor, populous and less so (figure 3a).
Figure 3a Global openness, 1870–2010 (PPP dollars)


Notes: This chart shows two global openness indices: a simple average (holding the sample constant of export-to-GDP ratios), and a population-weighted measure.

Sources: Maddison for historical estimates, Penn World Tables 7.1 for 1951–2010.

It has been widely documented that hyperglobalization can be attributed to the sharp drop in transportation costs and to the revolution in communication technologies. Hyperglobalization also reflects a more democratic distribution of world output (figure 3b). If there were one country with all or most of the world’s output, there would be zero or little trade. The more output is spread the more there will be trade. Since the mid-1990s, as poorer countries have started growing faster than rich ones (the phenomenon of “convergence”), output is being more equally (less unequally) spread over the globe, leading to an increase in trade. It is as if now there are more countries and hence more trade.
Figure 3b Dispersion of world output and world exports, 1970–2010


Notes: Country-equivalents , where si is the share of each country in world output. A higher number denotes a more equal distribution of output.
Source: UNCTAD

Criss-crossing Globalization
More than before, flows, and similar kinds of flows, are going in both directions. After World War II, similar goods were flowing (think cars) between the rich countries. With integrated supply chains, unfinished goods go back and forth. This is criss-crossing globalization. We illustrate this with the example of foreign direct investment (FDI). It is much harder today to speak about “receiving” and “sending” countries, as FDI goes in both directions, between rich countries themselves, but also increasingly with emerging market countries investing in the developed world.
Figure 4 Two-way foreign direct investment flows, 1970–2011


Note: The Grubel-Lloyd index is computed for each country with nonzero positive flows. Each country is then weighted by its share of total FDI flows, with weights corresponding to the current year (red line) or with weights that are fixed at their mean over the period (blue line). The figure shows five-year moving averages (to avoid large spikes).
Source:UNCTAD various years.

The Rise of a Mega-Trader—China—the First since Imperial Britain
China has become a “mega-trader” in two senses. First, it recently overtook the United States as the world’s largest trader. Under realistic growth projections, it will pull further away from the United States and other countries. Second, and more impressive, is that China is a mega-trader compared to its own characteristics: A country is expected to trade more relative to its GDP when it is richer and when its size is smaller. Controlling for those criteria, China substantially over-trades, only slightly less than the United Kingdom did at its peak. On this second criterion, the United States in its heyday and Japan in the 1980s were under-traders (figure 5).
Figure 5 Trade openness and population size
Britain: 1870

China: 2008

Note: We regress exports to GDP (in log) on size (population, in log) and income (GDP per capita, in log). For 2008, we exclude small (<5 million habitants) and oil exporting countries. The charts present the bivariate relation between size and openness, controlling for income. A country above the line is more open than expected given its size.
Source: Maddison for 1870, Penn World Tables for 2008

Rise of Preferential Agreements and Impending Rise of Mega-Regionalism
A lot of the liberalization in the era of hyperglobalization has occurred in the context of preferential trade agreements, which increasingly address “behind-the-border” barriers (see figure 6). In part, this is because the Doha Round of multilateral negotiations remained stalled. This trend will be reinforced with the two mega-regional agreements being negotiated by the United States, the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) with Asia, and the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP). About $2.5 trillion of trade in merchandise takes place within these two blocs, which accounts for 17 percent of world trade (the number would be higher if one includes services).
Figure 6 Number of new preferential trade agreements, 1958–2012

Source: World Trade Organization.

Decline of Formal Barriers
We have witnessed a long-term decline in tariffs across the world. This phenomenon is true across regions and has withstood the financial crisis, despite fears to the contrary.
Figure 7 Average most favored nation tariffs by income group, 1981–2009


MFN = most favored nation
Note: Spikes should not be over-interpreted as countries sometimes drop or enter the sample

Source: World Bank.

But Is the World Less Open Policy-wise?
There is a paradox: Liberalization is occurring all across the globe but the world may be getting more closed, or at least less open than people believe. This is because of two compositional shifts. Global output is moving away from less-protected manufacturing toward more-protected services (see figure 8) and from less-protected rich countries to more-protected poor countries (as shown in figures 7 and 8). Those shifts make the world as a whole less open and attenuate the liberalization trend that stems from all countries reducing barriers.
Figure 8 Index of services trade restrictiveness, by sector and region, 2008–10


Source: Borchert, Gootiz, and Mattoo 2012.

Nenhum comentário:

Postar um comentário

Comentários são sempre bem-vindos, desde que se refiram ao objeto mesmo da postagem, de preferência identificados. Propagandas ou mensagens agressivas serão sumariamente eliminadas. Outras questões podem ser encaminhadas através de meu site (www.pralmeida.org). Formule seus comentários em linguagem concisa, objetiva, em um Português aceitável para os padrões da língua coloquial.
A confirmação manual dos comentários é necessária, tendo em vista o grande número de junks e spams recebidos.