O que é este blog?

Este blog trata basicamente de ideias, se possível inteligentes, para pessoas inteligentes. Ele também se ocupa de ideias aplicadas à política, em especial à política econômica. Ele constitui uma tentativa de manter um pensamento crítico e independente sobre livros, sobre questões culturais em geral, focando numa discussão bem informada sobre temas de relações internacionais e de política externa do Brasil. Para meus livros e ensaios ver o website: www.pralmeida.org. Para a maior parte de meus textos, ver minha página na plataforma Academia.edu, link: https://itamaraty.academia.edu/PauloRobertodeAlmeida.

quarta-feira, 11 de dezembro de 2019

Why Economic Nationalism Fails - Dylan Pahman (Law and Liberty)

Nesta quarta-feira, 11/12/2019, compareci, pela manhã, ao Instituto Rio Branco, para assistir a uma conferência ministrada pelo professor Evandro Pontes, que traduziu para o português o livro The Virtue of Nationalism, de Yoram Hazony, vencedor do prêmio Conservative Book of the Year, de 2019. O professor Pontes abordou o pensamento de Hazony e sua aplicação à realidade brasileira. Ao final, solicitado a responder quais virtudes ele via no nacionalismo, título do livro traduzido por ele, disse que ainda não havia pensado na questão.
Eu confesso que não vejo nenhuma virtude, nem econômica, nem política, nem muito menos cultural. Acho o nacionalismo um atraso, em todos os sentidos...
Paulo Roberto de Almeida

Why Economic Nationalism Fails

This essay is adapted from remarks delivered by the author at the Philadelphia Society on October 19, 2019.
I will readily admit that I am neither a prophet nor the son of one. I do not know what the economic future of conservatism will be, but I can say something about what it ought to be. Conservatives ought to reaffirm the good of economic liberty, both domestically and internationally. Free markets and free trade, sustained by the rule of law and a culture of basic propriety, as Adam Smith outlined, ought to undergird the economic policy of any free and prosperous nation without neglecting the importance of non-state, non-economic spheres, such as religion and family.
However, at present economic liberty has fallen out of favor with some who see a sea change in recent events—from the election of President Trump in the United States to Great Britain’s “Brexit” referendum—moving away from a perceived elitist, globalist liberalism and back toward the old order of nation states, not only politically but also economically.
To some degree, this observation is correct. There is nothing all that new about the “national conservatism” of people like Yoram Hazony or Patrick Deneen. There has always been a nationalist and populist strand to conservatism, represented by the likes of Pat Buchanan, for example. On this view, immigration is presumed to be largely harmful, while tariffs, subsidies, and other protectionist economic policies are viewed as good and necessary. This not-so-new nationalism currently represents the most popular alternative to free markets and free trade among conservatives.
Which Nationalism?
That said, I’m an academic, so I’m a little dismayed by the lack of precision in the current debate. The recent “national conservatism” conference this summeris a case-in-point. It did a great job demonstrating the broad divergence of opinion among conservatives, from people like Yuval Levin and Richard Reinsch to Yoram Hazony and Patrick Deneen to former ambassador John Bolton and TV personality Tucker Carlson. These people do not together represent a coherent movement. Yet they all spoke under the same banner: a new, friendlier nationalism, a “national conservatism.”
The problem here is that nationalism can mean a lot of things. Without parsing out what those things are and discussing the extent of their desirability and compatibility, both those who support this new nationalism and its conservative critics are destined to misunderstand not only each other but even others who claim the same label. With that in mind, and with a view toward my stated goal of promoting an economically liberal future for conservatism (which is not a contradiction in terms), I offer the following four possible historic components of various nationalisms:
  1. Ethnic Nationalism – At its worst, this is the nationalism of Nazis, the KKK, and other “blood and soil” movements around the world. It is the nationalism no one in polite society wants to be associated with, and rightly so. That it is the original form of nationalism, however, must be admitted. The word “nation,” after all, comes from the Latin natio, which comes from nasci, meaning “birth.” Indeed, the English words “race” and “nation” were historically—and sometimes still are—used interchangeably, and ethnic nationalism is the belief that “the State and the nation [meaning race] must be co-extensive,” to quote Lord Acton, who notably, contra John Stuart Mill, opposed that theory. [1]
  2. Cultural Nationalism – This is often related to—but in my view separable from—ethnic nationalism. To value one’s national—or even ethnic—cultural achievements and to wish to preserve them does not require conflating one’s racial group with the state or other racial groups with hostile foreign powers. To be proud to be an American, for example, does not require one to be proud of everything the United States has ever done, including slavery, Jim Crow, or Wounded Knee. One may simply love democracy, the Protestant work ethic, hotdogs, and/or baseball (as all real Americans should).
  3. Political (or Civic) Nationalism – At their core, the many varieties of political nationalism put the principle of national sovereignty at the heart of domestic and international politics. In practice, this may come from sophisticated theory or populist sentiment. Militarily, it may be hawkish or embrace a more passive kind of restraint, as both invading other countries and staying out of foreign wars can be justified on the principle of national interest. The common ground comes down to where the decision to do so is made: not by a transnational governmental body, like the EU or UN, but by a sovereign national state.
  4. Economic Nationalism – This nationalism seeks to prioritize domestic industries over/against foreign imports. This is the nationalism behind “America first” economic policies, such as tariffs on foreign goods and subsidies for domestic manufacturers. Those today who claim the United States needs an “industrial policy” like Saudi Arabia are economic nationalists. They have so far rejected “zombie Reaganism” as to embrace the Frankenstein’s monster of Mondale conservatism.
Now, any particular nationalism may be a combination of several of these, and alternatively being sympathetic toward one or two of these may not be enough to classify one as “nationalist.” I am not a nationalist, for example, but I do think patriotism is a good thing and that national sovereignty and the national interest deserve their political due. That said, I am not a “globalist” or “imperialist” either. Rather, I am a classical liberal, and that extends into the domain of political economy.
Conversely, a nationalist may be a nationalist without necessarily embracing all of these nationalisms. Yoram Hazony, for example, is at pains in his book—and elsewhere—to distance his brand of nationalism from ethnic nationalism. In doing this, he conflates political and cultural nationalism, defining nations in terms of shared language, history, and religion, as well as the group loyalties arising from them. And there are some, like Senator Elizabeth Warren, who are primarily, if not entirely, economic nationalists, who may have little care for national sovereignty, patriotism, or cultural heritage.
Economic Nationalism vs. National Sovereignty
It is my contention, however, that while all of these nationalisms are separable, some are actually incompatible. In particular, the principle of national sovereignty is incompatible with the policies of economic nationalism.
Edmund Burke once remarked that “[o]f all things, an indiscreet tampering with the trade of provisions is the most dangerous…. [T]here is nothing on which the passions of men are so violent, and their judgment so weak, and on which there exists such a multitude of ill-founded popular prejudices.” Burke notably lauded the publication of Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations, and Smith’s insights therein about the positive-sum nature of exchange extend from the domestic trade of the butcher, the baker, and the brewer to the international trade between nations across the globe. What makes an exchange positive-sum is when it is faster and cheaper for me to buy something from you rather than making that thing myself, and vice versa. This is the principle of comparative advantage, a principle too many, under the sway of “ill-founded popular prejudices,” have lost sight of today.
The products that are a matter of a nation’s comparative advantage are those that its economy is the best at producing at any given time. Comparative advantages change over time, and it is a mistake to presume that yesterday’s comparative advantage still holds for today or tomorrow. Rather, exploiting one’s comparative advantages means prudently playing to one’s economic strengths and thereby strengthening one’s economy. A nation that knows and exploits its comparative advantages has greater power of self-determination internationally than one that does not. It has more to offer, more chips on the table, more with which it can bargain with others. And it is only free markets that allow for the coordination of information necessary for economic actors to continually adapt to the needs of any given moment. In this way, free markets and free trade strengthen national sovereignty.
To be clear, however, my first principle is neither liberty nor national sovereignty but natural law, without which liberty is but license and sovereignty illegitimate. There is such a thing as self-evident truth, originating from God, discoverable through reason, sanctified by religion, and confirmable through conscience. It is no coincidence that the global expansion of the free enterprise system—the economic arrangement most consistent with human nature—has also led to the most monumental reduction in poverty in human history. The overwhelming weight of evidence supports the conviction that when human beings, created in the image of God as free, rational, social, and moral animals, are allowed to creatively serve each other’s needs and responsibly plan their own lives, they flourish. And when a nation’s citizens flourish, the nation as a whole flourishes as well.
By contrast, economic nationalism actually injures national sovereignty as well as human flourishing. Despite the intention of punishing foreign competitors to domestic manufacturers, Russell Kirk rightly noted that “higher prices for consumers” is the result “within any country that sets high tariffs.” Tariffs do indeed mean fewer imports but, therefore, also higher prices and fewer choices for American families. According to President Trump’s Office of the United States Trade Representative, the president’s tariffs have affected a wide variety of meat, seafood, produce, chemicals, oils, rubber, luggage and other baggage, wood products (e.g., plywood, flooring), paper products, fabrics, glass, metals, electronic components, and more. Tariffs also mean less competition for domestic producers. Indeed, that is their explicit goal. However, less competition means a less dynamic economy, one more vulnerable to sudden changes and shocks, as the economic misfortunes of US Steel evidence, for example.
Furthermore, as our new nationalists today are ever wary of the evils of imperialism, I would remind them that no less than William F. Buckley called tariffs:
the meanest form of imperialism, in that [they are] a denial of economic ascendancy and a denial of hope to poorer nations for the sake of immediate short-term gain of competitors in the wealthier nations, which are strategically harmful in any event.
On this basis, he continued to argue, “It is … an obligation intellectual, historical, and ethical for young conservatives to reject facile calls for protectionist policies.” Tariffs make for a better instrument of imperialism than for supporting a global community of sovereign nation-states, as the EU, for example, knows well. It may be internally economically liberal between its member states, but it is externally more like a medieval guild of nations, unilaterally enacting duties and other restrictions on foreign imports on behalf of all its members.
Similarly at-odds with the national interest, subsidies for domestic industries prop up uncompetitive companies at the public’s expense. Kirk correctly called subsidies “costly economic mistakes.” California cotton subsidies, which persist despite yearly droughts, are a case-in-point. Other crops that require far less water, such as almonds, could more profitably be grown in the region in the absence of subsidies for cotton. Thus, the opportunity cost is not merely economic but also environmental in this case, which of course includes further negative externalities. On a national scale, as increased public spending is now routinely financed through increased debt to foreign powers—30 percent of public debt at present—national sovereignty, in that case, is directly undermined while economic growth is slowed or hindered. The protectionist policies of economic nationalism, therefore, are no recipe for national greatness.
Economic Freedom in the US Today
The good news for economic liberty is that there is more to it than eliminating subsidies and expanding the scope of international trade. Free markets are open markets—markets with as few barriers to entry as possible within the bounds of just laws. In fact, since President Trump’s election in 2016, the United States has actually improved its ratings in both the Fraser Institute’s Economic Freedom of the World report and the Heritage/Wall Street Journal Index of Economic Freedom. Many of my fellow free marketers have been far too pessimistic about the Trump administration, missing the forest of the economy as a whole for the few trees of increased tariffs and subsidies.
Conversely, however, many economic nationalists have misattributed our current economic strength to protectionism. Rather, this is due to significant deregulation and the reduction of the corporate tax down to a rate comparable to other developed countries. Our economy is stronger today than it was under President Obama because our economy is freer today than it was under President Obama. That said, when we look at specific metrics, we can see that while things like “business freedom” have improved, “trade freedom” and “fiscal health” are on the decline. At some point, the latter may outweigh the former, which would be bad news, indeed.
Conservatives today ought to reaffirm and promote economic liberty in its entirety, as did so many notable conservatives of the past, such as Edmund Burke, Russell Kirk, and William F. Buckley. This is not merely an issue of data points like GDP or the Gini coefficient. Rather it is a matter of the economic burden placed upon American families, the opportunities available to American workers, the markets available to American companies, and the strength of our nation both domestically and internationally. I do not know what direction the future holds. But if the tide of history has truly turned and support for free markets and free trade continues to decline on the right as well as the left, conservatives who have not lost sight of the principles and values they aim to conserve, ought to stand athwart history, yelling, “Stop!” when no one else will.
Economic Freedom and Religion
Indeed, the value of economic liberty extends beyond conventionally economic issues to some of those most valued by social conservatives. We must say, “Stop!” to those on the right and the left who would conflate the nation with a particular religious—or anti-religious—tradition. The sort of cultural nationalist that advocates for an established religion funded by a church tax shares this conflation of church and state with one-time Democratic presidential hopeful and unemployed skateboarder Beto O’Rourke, who wants to tax churches that do not conform their doctrines and practices to the progressive dogma of the day. A recent essay at First Things aptly labelled O’Rourke’s position “woke integralism.” In both cases, advocates must bring church and state into alignment and suppress their detractors. In this view, pluralism must be persecuted. Thus, it is not liberal but totalitarian.
Rather, religion should neither be subsidized nor taxed by the state. Religiosity has dramatically declined in precisely those European states that have retained established churches, and we all know of the mess that anti-religious movements like the French and Russian revolutions wrought upon the piety of those peoples. By contrast, religiosity remains high in the United States, where the market for religion continues to be one of the freest in the world. This religiosity has even endured letting in scary international imports, such as Roman Catholicism!
Despite the fears of religious conservatives, it is worth noting that in the United States those religious institutions that are in decline tend to be those that do not deliver on the product they claim to offer. When a church or other religious institution says, “Come here for salvation!” but all one hears inside are the mantras of popular political activism, it is no wonder that such institutions are not gaining members. By contrast, religious groups such as Orthodox Jews, Southern Baptists, and Mormons, all of whom prominently emphasize their distinctly spiritual character and call their members to rigorous moral and ascetic observance, tend to do quite well. Thus, O’Rourke’s claim that they and others should be compelled to alter their moral teaching about the nature of the family offers the prospect of financial ruin to those that would resist and declining influence and membership to those that would compromise, ultimately undermining religion in general no matter how any particular institution might respond. In the face of such illiberal proposals, conservatives must say, “Stop!”
Classical Liberalism and the Family
Speaking of the family, we must also say, “Stop!” to those like Yoram Hazony and Patrick Deneen who claim that classical liberalism presumes an atomistic individualism that undermines familial integrity. It does not. Not to their favorite boogeyman John Locke, at least. Regarding marriage, Locke wrote in his Two Treatises of Government that “GOD having made man such a creature, that in his own judgment, it was not good for him to be alone, put him under strong obligations of necessity, convenience, and inclination to drive him into society, as well as fitted him with understanding and language to continue and enjoy it. The first society,” he continues, “was between man and wife, which gave beginning to that between parents and children….”[2]
It may be objected that for Locke marriage is founded upon consent, and that is true, but even Hazony admits that much about 50 pages after criticizing Locke for saying the exact same thing. What is too often omitted by Locke’s critics is that he believed there to be duties between parents and children in a state of nature, that is, apart from any consent and as a matter of natural law. Contrary to Patrick Deneen, who claims classical liberal anthropology views human beings as “nonrelational creatures,” Locke actually believed that we are not self-sufficient, atomistic individuals, but that we are rather, by nature, “drive[n] … into society,” because it is “not good for [us] to be alone,” clearly alluding to Genesis 2:18.
Deneen does a little better reading Locke than Hazony, but not by much. He still finds insidious, radical individualism in Locke’s claim that adult children may choose whether or not to accept an inheritance from their parents. Locke does in fact say that, but Deneen overlooks the larger points that Locke was making: firstly, that if adult children do accept an inheritance they are at that point bound to terms that are not of their own making and beyond their consent. And secondly and more importantly, Locke was specifically objecting to the ancient Roman idea of a paterfamilias, who—at least on paper—retained absolute control over his wife and children, including their very lives, until his death. Does Deneen not think adults should get to make their own decisions so long as their fathers live?
Furthermore, Locke clearly differentiates the family from “political society” due to the different “ends, ties, and bounds” of family relationships, i.e., due its unique nature and teleology. Thus, conflating Locke’s understanding of political society and the family, the latter of which is founded as much upon nature as consent, grossly misrepresents his views. When one takes the time to understand Locke in context, the new nationalist narrative reads more like sloppy historical fiction than serious historical criticism. Last I checked, conservatives were supposed to value history, rather than distort it to serve present-day political ends.
Indeed, in addition to Locke, when we look at the earliest modern representative governments, as is well-known, the franchise was commonly restricted to heads of households, indicating that these first modern liberal democracies all viewed the household or family as the most basic unit rather than the individual. Now, call me a radical, but I personally support women’s suffrage. On that account I will happily be accused of individualism. But one could not fairly charge most early classical liberals with radical individualism even on that account. Indeed, the economist Frank Knight succinctly summarized this point in 1939, stating that “in the nature of the case, liberalism is more ‘familism’ than literal individualism. Some sort of family life, and far beyond that, some kind of wider primary-group must be taken as they are, as data, in free society at any time….”[3] Classical liberalism does not undermine the family by presuming an atomistic individual. Rather, as the historical record shows, it starts with the family, thus presuming it.
Classical liberalism’s emphasis on the family also has an economic aspect, evinced by the fact that intact, two-parent families thrive in relatively free economies like the United States. Healthy families increase their children’s likelihood of economic success. As one recent study concluded, “People raised outside stable two-parent families are more likely to be in the lowest income quintile as adults and less likely to be in the highest quintile than people raised in stable two-parent families.”[3] In a fairly free economy like the United States, healthy homes make for more favorable economic outcomes. Free markets reward healthy families and thus support, rather than undermine, them. The importance of healthy families, then, ought to be part of any future free market political economy for conservatives.
The Common Benefit of All
Cultural, non-state, non-economic institutions, like religion and family, matter for a free and prosperous economy as well as free markets and free trade, and it is conservatives in the United States who historically have understood that best. Whatever our coming economy may look like, conservatives should say, “Stop!” to any economistic, technocratic, or purely political solutions to social problems. Nations, I hope we can all agree, are far more than simply the market plus the state. Families, religious institutions, schools, and other spheres of society all have vital roles to contribute not only to the common good but also to the national economy.
My background is theology. Given that background, I’d like to conclude with a quote from the medieval Christian theologian Hugh of St. Victor. Not only do non-economic spheres contribute to the economy, but a healthy, free economy also contributes to all those other spheres of life. “Commerce,” he wrote, “penetrates the secret places of the world, approaches shores unseen, explores fearful wildernesses, and in tongues unknown and with barbaric peoples carries on the trade of mankind. The pursuit of commerce reconciles nations, calms wars, strengthens peace, and commutes the private good of individuals into the common benefit of all.”[4] The expansion of economic liberty since the Industrial Revolution and the monumental, qualitative improvements to human life occasioned by it testify to the veracity of this conviction. Rather than turn our backs on the legacy of economic liberty we’ve built and received in the United States and in the West more broadly, conservatives today ought to further its advancement for the strength of our nation and families, the peace of the world, and “the common benefit of all.”

[1] That both Acton and Mill were liberals demonstrates additional terminological problems, as liberalism and nationalism are commonly set opposite one another today. Addressing this is outside the scope of this essay, however, and I honestly find the current distinction convenient, even if ahistorical. On this see Lord Acton, “Nationality,” in Lord Acton: Historical and Moral Essays, ed. Daniel J. Hugger (Grand Rapids: Acton Institute, 2017), 112.
[2] John Locke, Two Treatises of Government, new ed. (London: Whitmore and Fenn; C. Brown, 1821 [1690]), 252-253
[3] Dierdre Bloome, “Childhood Family Structure and Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States,” Demography 54, no. 2 (April 2017): 541-569. The quotation here is from the draft version, emphasis added.
[4] Hugh of St. Victor, Didascalicon, trans. Jerome Taylor (New York; Lordon: Columbia University Press, 1961), 2.23, 77.

Dylan Pahman is a research fellow at the Acton Institute for the Study of Religion & Liberty, where he serves as managing editor of the Journal of Markets & Morality. He is the author of Foundations of a Free & Virtuous Society(2017). Follow him on Twitter: @DylanPahman.

O poder das ideias econômicas - Seminário, Roma, junho 2020

STOREP 2020 - "The Power of Economic Ideas" (Roma, June 25-27, 2019) 
Call for papers 

The 17th Annual STOREP Conference will be held at the Università di Roma Tor Vergata, Facoltà di Economia, Dipartimento di Economia e Finanza, Via Columbia 2, 00133 Roma, on June 25-27, 2020. The title of the Conference is “The Power of Economic Ideas” (webpage).
“The ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed the world is ruled by little else”. These words by Keynes invite us to reflect on the role of economic theory in shaping the economy and to go beyond conventional wisdom, which sees theory as neutral with respect to the world it describes.  Reflection on the power of economic ideas will take us to explore three paths, policies, institutions and individuals, which together shape the economic system and its connections with society.
From the debate on free trade, at the time of Ricardo, to different views on fiscal policy and its contribution to stabilization and growth, examples abound regarding the role of ideas in shaping economic policies and institutions. Independent central banks, privatization of services formerly provided by the Welfare State, from pensions to health services and education, new markets to trade CO2 and electricity are all examples of institutions, designed to be consistent with the precepts of orthodox economic theory and its confidence in markets and their allocative function. A similar attitude pervades those who believe that rational individuals respond to economic incentives in a way, which can be empirically documented and exploited to improve institutional and policy design.
In distant and recent years, economists and historians of economic thought have expressed doubts about the possibility of improving society by relying exclusively on individual incentives and markets. These doubts echo recent debates on the limits of homo oeconomicus, representative-agent modelling and the idea that there is no such thing as society, but only individual men and women. Researchers who believe in the need to go beyond the representative agent explore different issues, including financialization, inequality, economic, environmental and urban issues, social dynamics, cooperation and social norms. The 2020 STOREP Annual Conference in Rome invites contributions that explore the power of economic ideas from a variety of perspectives: history of economics, economic history, a plurality of theoretical approaches and cooperation with other disciplines. Possible topics for the conference sessions include, but are not limited to:
  • Macroeconomic policies and their theoretical underpinnings
  • Europe and competing approaches to its consolidation
  • Globalization and economic development between myth and reality
  • Economic theory between defence and critique of capitalism
  • Performativity and its relevance for market and policy design
  • Wage and employment issues and their gender and distributive implications
  • Incentive-based policies and their influence on health and the environment
  • Financialization and challenges to the efficient market hypothesis
  • Experimental investigations of market and social interaction
  • The failures of economics as “social” science and the need for interdisciplinary cooperation
Proposals of papers in all fields adopting a historical perspective and/or comparing different approaches to economic issues are also welcome.
STOREP welcomes special sessions jointly organized with other scientific associations, and invites these latter to submit proposals.
We are pleased to announce that distinguished colleague Professor Amos Witztum (London School of Economics and Political Science and Centre for Philosophy of Natural and Social Science, CPNSS) will join the conference as keynote speaker.
Professor Sheila Dow (University of Stirling, UK, and University of Victoria, Canada) will deliver the fourth “Raffaelli lecture”.
The 2020 STOREP Conference will jointly organize initiatives and special sessions with the Institute for New Economic Thinking (and the “Young Scholars Initiative”) as well as with students and researchers of the international network “Rethinking Economics”.
Selected papers on the main topic of the conference will be considered for publication in the Review of Political Economy and Economia & Lavoro.
Proposals submission
The deadline for abstract and session proposals is March 15, 2020. Notification of accepted and rejected abstracts and sessions will be sent by March 30, 2020.
Proposals must be uploaded on the Submission website of the conference - i.e. via web-based software "Conference maker". To submit, please create an account, by providing basic contact info and choosing a user ID/password. If you signed up for a previous conference using Conference Maker, you can login with your existing user ID and password.
Abstract proposals (with keywords, JEL codes, and affiliation) must not exceed 400 words. Session proposals should include the abstract of the three scheduled papers.
Registration
May 20, 2019: Deadline for early registration (early fees).
June 10, 2019: Deadline for submitting full papers.
All participants, including young scholars who apply for the awards, must become STOREP members or renew their membership (instructions here).
All relevant information concerning registration fees, accommodation and programme will soon be published on the STOREP website.
Young Scholars STOREP Awards
STOREP provides deserving young scholars with two kinds of scholarship grants.
1) A number of Scholarships for young scholars (under 40 years of age, non tenured). In order to be eligible, the applicant is required to submit a Curriculum Vitae and an extended abstract on any topic relevant to the history of political economy, by March 15, 2020 (applicants have to pick the option "Young Scholars" as "Area" of reference for their paper when submitting via the website; they can then use the "Second choice area" to specify the category of their paper - e.g. history of economic thought, macroeconomics, etc.). The final version of the papers must be uploaded within May 20, 2020. Applicants will be informed about the result of the evaluation process no later than May 25, 2020. The authors of the papers selected will be awarded free STOREP Conference registration, including the social dinner and the association’s annual membership fee, as well as, if possible, a lump sum contribution to travel and staying expenses.
2) The two STOREP Awards (of 1000 € each) for the best articles presented at the Annual Conference by young scholars under 40 years of age. All applications, with CV and the final version of the papers, should be sent to segretario@storep.org no later than September 15, 2020. Only papers co-authored by no more than 3 researchers, who all meet the requirements for belonging to the “Young” scholars, are eligible for the Award. Winning recipients of the award in one of the three preceding rounds cannot apply.

17th Annual STOREP Conference
Organizing Committee
Angela Ambrosino (Università di Torino)
Mario Cedrini (Università di Torino)
Maria Cristina Marcuzzo (Università di Roma La Sapienza)
Paolo Paesani (Università di Roma Tor Vergata)
Annalisa Rosselli (Università di Roma Tor Vergata)
Giulia Zacchia (Università di Roma La Sapienza)
Scientific Committee
Carlo D’Ippoliti (Università di Roma La Sapienza)
Maria Cristina Marcuzzo (Università di Roma La Sapienza)
Paolo Paesani (Università di Roma Tor Vergata)
Antonella Palumbo (Università Roma Tre)
Annalisa Rosselli (Università di Roma Tor Vergata)
Antonella Stirati (Università Roma Tre)

Mario CedriniSTOREP Secretary
Associazione Italiana per la Storia dell'Economia Politica / Italian Association for the History of Political Economy

www.storep.org
www.facebook.com/STOREP.org


Ensino superior no Brasil está sofrendo ataque`, mostra relatório internacional

Ensino superior no Brasil está sofrendo ataque`, mostra relatório internacional
POR AGÊNCIA O GLOBO - IG EDUCAÇÃO – 10/12/2019 – SÃO PAULO, SP

Os repetidos ataques às universidades públicas desde a campanha eleitoral do ano passado, que prosseguiram após a eleição de Jair Bolsonaro, levaram o Brasil a ser o destaque negativo do relatório ` Free to Think ` (livre para pensar), publicado pela rede internacional Scholars at Risk (acadêmicos em risco), baseada na Universidade de Nova York.
A edição deste ano do documento tem sua capa ilustrada pela foto de uma das manifestações a favor da educação no Brasil, e o país também é tema de um capítulo próprio, intitulado `Ataque ao espaço do ensino superior no Brasil `.
`No Brasil, pressões sobre comunidades universitárias dispararam desde as eleições presidenciais do país, em outubro de 2018. Invasões policiais em campi, relatos de estudantes e professores membros de minorias sendo ameaçados e atacados dentro e fora dos campi e ações orçamentárias e legislativas para minar as instituições de ensino superior e limitar a liberdade acadêmica e a autonomia institucional refletem crescentes preocupações encontradas em outras nações onde o conceito de `democracia iliberal` ganhou força entre os líderes`, afirma o relatório.
Entre os exemplos de ataques no Brasil, o documento cita o estupro, em 25 de outubro de 2018, de uma aluna negra da Universidade de Fortaleza (Unifor) que havia recebido `inúmeras ameaças racistas on-line e pessoalmente`.
`O ataque ocorreu em um contexto de uma série de ataques politicamente motivados contra minorias e membros da comunidade LGBTQ perpetrado por apoiadores do então candidato a presidente Jair Bolsonaro . Antes do incidente, a aluna havia sido assediada e ameaçada por um homem que afirmou que ele e outros `purificariam a universidade` de `seu povo` quando Bolsonaro assumisse o cargo`, diz o relatório.
Segundo o documento, a Unifor condenou o ataque e ofereceu à vítima aconselhamento psicológico e jurídico. Até a publicação dele, o autor ainda não havia sido identificado.
Outro exemplo citado foi o ataque, em 19 de outubro do ano passado, a quinze estudantes da Universidade Federal do Estado do Rio de Janeiro (UFRJ) que faziam campanha para o então candidato à presidência Fernando Haddad do lado de fora do campus.

Críticas a Weintraub
O documento também cita as ações do ministro da Educação, Abraham Weintraub , incluindo sua acusação de que três universidades federais — a Fluminense (UFF), a de Brasília (UnB) e a da Bahia (UFBA)— promoviam ` balbúrdia ` e sua ameaça de reduzir os recursos às faculdades de filosofia e sociologia.
Em suas conclusões, o relatório urge o governo brasileiro a `tomar medidas razoáveis para garantir a segurança dos acadêmicos, estudantes, funcionários e outros membros de comunidades de ensino superior, inclusive investigando incidentes e responsabilizando seus autores`.
Pede também que os membros da administração abstenham-se `de declarações ou ações que estigmatizem o ensino superior, acadêmicos ou estudantes e corroem as condições de segurança, liberdade acadêmica ou autonomia institucional das instituições brasileiras de ensino`.
Em entrevista à BBC News Brasil , o diretor-executivo da Scholars at Risk , Robert Quinn, afirmou que a inclusão do país no relatório deste ano não signifiica que ele é o que mais restringe a liberdade acadêmica, mas chama atenção pelo ineditismo —os relatos que a ONG recebeu de acadêmicos que se dizem vítima de perseguição nunca foram tão numerosos.
`Há algo acontecendo e precisamos olhar para isso. Não quer dizer que há um grande problema, mas significa que precisamos analisar. E, quando olhamos, uma parte dos incidentes foi muito bem pronunciada por representantes do governo ou políticos no Brasil. Algumas destas falas circularam pelo mundo`, disse Quinn à BBC Brasil.
O GLOBO procurou o Ministério da Educação para que a pasta comentasse o relatório `Free to Think`, mas não obteve resposta até a conclusão deste texto.

NAFTA e USMCA são mais parecidos do que diferentes - CNN

5 key differences between NAFTA and Trump's USMCA deal


Washington (CNN, December 11, 2019)  After reaching a deal on the final version of the United States-Mexico-Canada Agreement, President Donald Trump tweeted that it "will be the best and most important trade deal ever made by the USA" -- and called its predecessor, the North American Free Trade Agreement, "our Country's worst Trade Deal." 
House Speaker Nancy Pelosi echoed that view, saying in her announcement that "there is no question of course that this trade agreement is much better than NAFTA."
But the two deals are far more alike than they are different -- and the impact of the renegotiated agreement may not be that big. In April, the US International Trade Commission, a federal government agency, found the initial version of the USMCA would create 176,000 jobs after six years and increase the GDP by 0.35% -- an impact the agency described as "moderate." (For comparison's sake: The US added 266,000 new jobs in November alone.) The full final version has not yet been released publicly.
Here are five key differences between the two agreements:

Auto manufacturing boost


The USMCA requires 75% of a vehicle's parts to be made in one of the three countries -- up from the current 62.5% rule -- in order to remain free from tariffs when moving between the three signatory countries.
It also requires more vehicle parts to be made by workers earning at least $16 an hour, which may provide a boost to manufacturing in the United States, where wages are higher than in Mexico. 
The International Trade Commission report found that these changes would add 28,000 jobs in the industry over six years, while also leading to a small increase in the price of vehicles that consumers pay.
But the American Automotive Policy Council, which represents General Motors, Ford and Fiat-Chrysler, argued the ITC report underestimated the long-term investments US automakers will make because of the USMCA. 
A Trump administration report was more positive, projecting that the deal would create 76,000 auto jobs over five years. That would mean a more than 7% increase in employment over the current 990,000 US auto workers.
On Tuesday, the trade group said the big three automakers were "pleased" that the USMCA was moving forward. 
"The USMCA allows the US auto industry to remain globally competitive by ensuring vehicles and auto parts are able to move freely across country lines," said Matt Blunt, president of the American Automotive Policy Council, in a statement
But auto plants are capital intensive and it takes a long time to move production. Industry analysts have said that some automakers may opt to pay the tariff at least at first, rather than move plants or shift hiring. 
A GM spokesperson said Tuesday that the company had already made numerous changes in anticipation of the more stringent standards set by the USMCA, including shifting production plans of a new Chevrolet electric vehicle back to the United States, and building a new GM/LG battery plant near Lordstown, Ohio. 

Labor laws strengthened


Manufacturing workers have long blamed NAFTA for sending jobs to Mexico, where wages are lower, and it was a priority for Democrats that the USMCA strengthen the enforcement of labor rules, creating a more level playing field for American workers. 
Lawmakers were able to include some changes to enforcement language before coming to an agreement Tuesday with the Trump administration, and the deal now has the backing of the AFL-CIO, the largest federation of unions in the US. 
"For the first time, there truly will be enforceable labor standards -- including a process that allows for the inspections of factories and facilities that are not living up to their obligations," said AFL-CIO President Richard Trumka in a statement. 
The deal struck by Democrats provides for an interagency committee that will monitor Mexico's labor reform implementation and compliance with labor obligations and a set of benchmarks for Mexico to meet in implementing the reforms.

Dairy farmers get more market access


The original NAFTA eliminated tariffs on most agricultural products traded among the three countries. Canada and Mexico are already the two biggest export markets for US farmers and ranchers. 
The USMCA will keep those tariffs at zero, while also further opening up the Canadian market to US dairy, poultry and eggs. In return, the United States will allow more Canadian dairy, peanuts and peanut products, as well as a limited amount of sugar, to cross the border. 

Updating NAFTA for the digital era


The USMCA includes sweeping new benefits for the technology sector, in a chapter on digital trade that wasn't a part of the original NAFTA. The new provisions aren't expected to directly create new jobs, but could provide a boost to US businesses in other ways. 
For example, the new trade deal prohibits Canada and Mexico from forcing US companies to store their data on in-country servers. It also ensures that US companies cannot be sued in Canada and Mexico for much of the content appearing on their platforms -- a legal protection Pelosi had pushed to exclude from USMCA amid an ongoing debate at home about whether tech companies still deserve that liability shield under domestic law.

Congress keeps control over biologic drugs


Democrats negotiated the removal of what would have been new, controversial protections for biologic drugs. They argue it would have hamstrung Congress from being able to legislate on drug pricing issues.
The provision that was removed from the trade deal would have required the three countries to provide at least 10 years of exclusivity for biologics, which are complex and costly to make. Currently, the US provides 12 years of exclusivity, while Canada provides eight years and Mexico five years.
Republicans have long supported including exclusivity provisions for pharmaceutical companies in trade deals, and the pharmaceutical industry quickly came out against the provision's removal.
"Eliminating the biologics provision in the USMCA removes vital protections for innovators while doing nothing to help US patients afford their medicines or access future treatments and cures," said Stephen Ubl, CEO of PhRMA, a trade group. "The only winners today are foreign governments who want to steal American intellectual property and free ride on America's global leadership in biopharmaceutical research and development."

CNN's Vanessa Yurkevich and Holmes Lybrand contributed to this story.

UE vai taxar Estados que não cumprirem Acordo de Paris

Europa se prepara para taxar importações de países que não cumprirem acordo do clima

Medida pode fazer parte do pacote conhecido como Green New Deal

Daniela Chiarelli, Valor Econômico, 11/12/2019

MADRI - A ideia de uma taxa de ajuste de fronteira começa a tomar corpo na União Europeia (UE). Nesta quarta-feira, a Comissão Europeia pode propor a ideia durante reunião do bloco . Esta é uma das peças mais controversas do pacote climático da nova presidente, Ursula von der Leyen, que o bloco ameaça criar.
O vice-presidente executivo da Comissão Europeia , o holandês Frans Timmermans, foi vago sobre quais elementos estarão dentro do pacote climático que será discutido esta semana em Bruxelas e que vem sendo conhecido como o “Green New Deal” europeu.

Mas Timmermans deixou claro, durante entrevista coletiva na COP-25 de Madri, que a UE não hesitaria em impor medidas para proteger sua indústria de concorrentes que não respeitarem o Acordo de Paris.
Foi uma resposta à pergunta sobre a possibilidade de o bloco adotar uma taxa de carbono às importações de concorrentes com alta emissão:
- Se queremos atingir as metas que estabelecemos no Acordo de Paris, isso exigirá medidas. Vamos tomar estas medidas. Se você tomar as mesmas medidas ou algo comparável, não haverá nada a corrigir na fronteira. - Mas se não [fizer isso], claro, em determinado momento teremos que proteger a nossa indústria, que assumiu estes compromissos. Não queremos colocar a nossa indústria em uma posição mais fraca que as outras - afirmou Timmermans, acrescentando:
- Espero que não haja necessidade de tomar esta medida. Mas se for necessário, não hesitaremos.
O vice-presidente executivo da Comissão Europeia, o holandês Frans Timmermans Foto: Francois Lenoir / Reuters
O vice-presidente executivo da Comissão Europeia, o holandês Frans Timmermans Foto: Francois Lenoir / Reuters

Reações à proposta de taxa de ajuste de fronteira

Na semana passada, o professor He Jiankun, da Tsinghua University, que está com a delegação chinesa, reagiu à ideia de a UE criar uma taxa de ajuste de fronteira. Lembrou que o Acordo de Paris estabelece cooperações multilaterais “e que um ato unilateral deixa muitas questões em aberto”.

- Como isso seria? - questionou He. - Seria para todos os países ou não? Seria a mesma taxa para todos os produtos? Como ter um tratamento justo?-  indagou. - Estas são perguntas que me ocorrem. Mas acredito que uma medida unilateral pode ter impacto na atmosfera franca do Acordo de Paris.
Timmermans adiantou que na cúpula europeia desta semana, em Bruxelas, será apresentada a taxa de descarbonização de longo prazo do bloco, para 2050.
- Vejo o sentido de urgência aumentando entre os Estados membros, mas também vejo preocupação porque isso representará uma grande mudança na estrutura econômica, no mix energético. Mas estes países verão que fazem parte do esforço europeu e terão a solidariedade do resto da UE.

O bloco quer “liderar pelo exemplo”, diz ele, mas como responde por apenas 9% das emissões globais, “é realmente importante se pudermos convencer os outros parceiros a se movimentar na mesma direção”.
Estas decisões preparam o bloco para a cúpula que pretendem ter com a China em Leipzig, em setembro.
- Há desafios geopolíticos, a guerra comercial não ajuda, confrontações não ajudam. Mas ao mesmo tempo, um crescimento econômico menor também não ajuda - disse Timmermans.  - A liderança chinesa tem mostrado consistentemente sua consciência da necessidade de enfrentar as emissões globais - continuou.

Ele diz acreditar que há uma “boa base” para UE e China chegarem a um acordo durante a cúpula de setembro.
Sobre os EUA, o vice-presidente da Comissão Europeia disse que tem observado a “miríade” de esforços locais que vem sendo feita no país:
- Mas confesso que tenho pouca paciência com negacionistas, porque a ciência climática é tão robusta.
Timmermans seguiu:
- Isso não é apenas bom para o clima e para o meio ambiente, mas é bom para a economia. É para onde a economia está se movendo. E é bom para os empregos, no longo prazo. Como neto de mineiros de carvão, todos sabemos que este não é o futuro.

Entendimento com o Brasil

Sobre a ideia do atual governo brasileiro, de que os países desenvolvidos deveriam pagar os em desenvolvimento para manter as florestas , e também à implementação do artigo 6, Timmermans alegou não ter falado com o ministro do Meio Ambiente, Ricardo Salles .
- Por razões pessoais, durante décadas tive uma incrível fascinação pelo Brasil. Não posso imaginar que não chegaremos a um ponto em comum de entendimento sobre como vamos proteger os nossos bens globais comuns como as florestas tropicais-, adiantou. - Mas também tenho que ser muito claro: qualquer acordo que tivermos deve ajudar a nos mover adiante, em Paris, e não para trás.

(*) A jornalista viajou à COP-25  a convite do Instituto Clima e Sociedade (iCS)