O governo atual, aliás desde 2003, tem um grande problema de concepção: os companheiros que entendem um pouquinho de economia, e que se pretendem orientadores da política econômica do governo, são todos keynesianos de botequim, ou seja, cepalianos vulgares que estão prejudicando a economia e os trabalhadores, em lugar de ajudar, muito longe do que eles pretendiam.
Existem dezenas de exemplos de políticas equivocadas e mesmo de crimes econômicos, cometidos contra os interesses do Brasil e dos trabalhadores.
Parece que não adianta argumentar com eles, pois são obtusos, obstinados, teimosos.
Talvez este artigo sobre a história econômica da Grande Depressão, nos EUA dos anos 1930, sirva para ensinar alguma coisa a esses patriotas equivocados.
O artigo é exclusivamente sobre as políticas econômicas do New Deal, mas ele tem tudo a ver com as concepções erradas dos companheiros que se acreditam desenvolvimentistas e são só trapalhões...
Paulo Roberto de Almeida
Harold L. Cole and
Lee E. Ohanian
The Wall Street journal, February 2, 2009
The New Deal is widely perceived to have
ended the Great Depression, and this has led many to support a "new" New
Deal to address the current crisis. But the facts do not support the
perception that FDR's policies shortened the Depression, or that similar
policies will pull our nation out of its current economic downturn.
The goal of the New Deal was to get
Americans back to work. But the New Deal didn't restore employment. In
fact, there was even less work on average during the New Deal than
before FDR took office. Total hours worked per adult, including
government employees, were 18% below their 1929 level between 1930-32,
but were 23% lower on average during the New Deal (1933-39). Private
hours worked were even lower after FDR took office, averaging 27% below
their 1929 level, compared to 18% lower between in 1930-32.
Even
comparing hours worked at the end of 1930s to those at the beginning of
FDR's presidency doesn't paint a picture of recovery. Total hours
worked per adult in 1939 remained about 21% below their 1929 level,
compared to a decline of 27% in 1933. And it wasn't just work that
remained scarce during the New Deal. Per capita consumption did not
recover at all, remaining 25% below its trend level throughout the New
Deal, and per-capita nonresidential investment averaged about 60% below
trend. The Great Depression clearly continued long after FDR took
office.
Why wasn't the Depression
followed by a vigorous recovery, like every other cycle? It should have
been. The economic fundamentals that drive all expansions were very
favorable during the New Deal. Productivity grew very rapidly after
1933, the price level was stable, real interest rates were low, and
liquidity was plentiful. We have calculated on the basis of just
productivity growth that employment and investment should have been back
to normal levels by 1936. Similarly, Nobel Laureate Robert Lucas and
Leonard Rapping calculated on the basis of just expansionary Federal
Reserve policy that the economy should have been back to normal by 1935.
So what stopped a blockbuster recovery from
ever starting? The New Deal. Some New Deal policies certainly benefited
the economy by establishing a basic social safety net through Social
Security and unemployment benefits, and by stabilizing the financial
system through deposit insurance and the Securities Exchange Commission.
But others violated the most basic economic principles by suppressing
competition, and setting prices and wages in many sectors well above
their normal levels. All told, these antimarket policies choked off
powerful recovery forces that would have plausibly returned the economy
back to trend by the mid-1930s.
The most
damaging policies were those at the heart of the recovery plan,
including The National Industrial Recovery Act (NIRA), which tossed
aside the nation's antitrust acts and permitted industries to
collusively raise prices provided that they shared their newfound
monopoly rents with workers by substantially raising wages well above
underlying productivity growth. The NIRA covered over 500 industries,
ranging from autos and steel, to ladies hosiery and poultry production.
Each industry created a code of "fair competition" which spelled out
what producers could and could not do, and which were designed to
eliminate "excessive competition" that FDR believed to be the source of
the Depression.
These codes distorted
the economy by artificially raising wages and prices, restricting
output, and reducing productive capacity by placing quotas on industry
investment in new plants and equipment. Following government approval of
each industry code, industry prices and wages increased substantially,
while prices and wages in sectors that weren't covered by the NIRA, such
as agriculture, did not. We have calculated that manufacturing wages
were as much as 25% above the level that would have prevailed without
the New Deal. And while the artificially high wages created by the NIRA
benefited the few that were fortunate to have a job in those industries,
they significantly depressed production and employment, as the growth
in wage costs far exceeded productivity growth.
These
policies continued even after the NIRA was declared unconstitutional in
1935. There was no antitrust activity after the NIRA, despite
overwhelming FTC evidence of price-fixing and production limits in many
industries, and the National Labor Relations Act of 1935 gave unions
substantial collective-bargaining power. While not permitted under
federal law, the sit-down strike, in which workers were occupied
factories and shut down production, was tolerated by governors in a
number of states and was used with great success against major
employers, including General Motors in 1937.
The
downturn of 1937-38 was preceded by large wage hikes that pushed wages
well above their NIRA levels, following the Supreme Court's 1937
decision that upheld the constitutionality of the National Labor
Relations Act. These wage hikes led to further job loss, particularly in
manufacturing. The "recession in a depression" thus was not the result
of a reversal of New Deal policies, as argued by some, but rather a
deepening of New Deal polices that raised wages even further above their
competitive levels, and which further prevented the normal forces of
supply and demand from restoring full employment. Our research indicates
that New Deal labor and industrial policies prolonged the Depression by
seven years.
By the late 1930s, New
Deal policies did begin to reverse, which coincided with the beginning
of the recovery. In a 1938 speech, FDR acknowledged that the American
economy had become a "concealed cartel system like Europe," which led
the Justice Department to reinitiate antitrust prosecution. And union
bargaining power was significantly reduced, first by the Supreme Court's
ruling that the sit-down strike was illegal, and further reduced during
World War II by the National War Labor Board (NWLB), in which large
union wage settlements were limited by the NWLB to cost-of-living
increases. The wartime economic boom reflected not only the enormous
resource drain of military spending, but also the erosion of New Deal
labor and industrial policies.
By 1947, through a combination of NWLB wage
restrictions and rapid productivity growth, we have calculated that the
large gap between manufacturing wages and productivity that emerged
during the New Deal had nearly been eliminated. And since that time,
wages have never approached the severely distorted levels that prevailed
under the New Deal, nor has the country suffered from such abysmally
low employment.
The main lesson we have
learned from the New Deal is that wholesale government intervention can
-- and does -- deliver the most unintended of consequences. This was
true in the 1930s, when artificially high wages and prices kept us
depressed for more than a decade, it was true in the 1970s when price
controls were used to combat inflation but just produced shortages. It
is true today, when poorly designed regulation produced a banking system
that took on too much risk.
President
Barack Obama
and Congress have a great opportunity to produce reforms that do return
Americans to work, and that provide a foundation for sustained long-run
economic growth and the opportunity for all Americans to succeed. These
reforms should include very specific plans that update banking
regulations and address a manufacturing sector in which several large
industries -- including autos and steel -- are no longer internationally
competitive. Tax reform that broadens rather than narrows the tax base
and that increases incentives to work, save and invest is also needed.
We must also confront an educational system that fails many of its
constituents. A large fiscal stimulus plan that doesn't directly address
the specific impediments that our economy faces is unlikely to achieve
either the country's short-term or long-term goals.
Mr.
Cole is professor of economics at the University of Pennsylvania. Mr.
Ohanian is professor of economics and director of the Ettinger Family
Program in Macroeconomic Research at UCLA.